History of banking
Part of a series on financial services |
Banking |
---|
The history of banking began with the first prototype banks, that is, the merchants of the world, who gave grain loans to farmers and traders who carried goods between cities. This was around 2000 BCE in Assyria, India and Sumer. Later, in ancient Greece and during the Roman Empire, lenders based in temples gave loans, while accepting deposits and performing the change of money. Archaeology from this period in ancient China and India also show evidences of money lending.[citation needed]
Many scholars trace the historical roots of the modern banking system to medieval and Renaissance Italy, particularly the affluent cities of Florence, Venice and Genoa. The Bardi and Peruzzi families dominated banking in 14th century Florence, establishing branches in many other parts of Europe.[1] The most famous Italian bank was the Medici Bank, established by Giovanni Medici in 1397.[2] The oldest bank still in existence is Banca Monte dei Paschi di Siena, headquartered in Siena, Italy, which has been operating continuously since 1472.[3] Until the end of 2002, the oldest bank still in operation was the Banco di Napoli headquartered in Naples, Italy, which had been operating since 1463.
Development of banking spread from northern Italy throughout the Holy Roman Empire, and in the 15th and 16th century to northern Europe. This was followed by a number of important innovations that took place in Amsterdam during the Dutch Republic in the 17th century, and in London since the 18th century. During the 20th century, developments in telecommunications and computing caused major changes to banks' operations and let banks dramatically increase in size and geographic spread. The 2007–2008 financial crisis led to many bank failures, including some of the world's largest banks, and provoked much debate about bank regulation.
Ancient authority
[edit]The shift from a reliance on hunting and gathering of foods to agricultural practices, starting sometime after 12,000 BCE, resulted in increased stability of economic relations. Such changes in socio-economic conditions began approximately 10,000 years ago in the Fertile Crescent, about 9,500 years ago in northern China, about 5,500 years ago in Mexico, and approximately 4,500 years ago in the eastern parts of the United States.[4][5][6]
Monetary
[edit]Ancient types of money known as grain-money and food cattle-money were used from around 9000 BCE as two of the earliest commodities used for purposes of bartering.
Anatolian obsidian as a raw material for Stone Age tools was being distributed from as early as about 12,500 BCE, and organized trading of it was occurring during the 9th millennium BCE (Cauvin; Chataigner 1989). Sardinia was one of the four main sites for sourcing the material deposits of obsidian within the Mediterranean; trade using obsidian was replaced during the 3rd millennium BCE by trade of copper and silver.
Record-keeping
[edit]Objects used for record keeping, "bulla" and tokens, have been recovered from within Near East excavations, dated to a period beginning 8000 BCE and ending 1500 BCE, as records of the counting of agricultural produce. Commencing in the late fourth millennia mnemonic symbols were in use by members of temples and palaces to record stocks of produce. Types of records accounting for trade exchanges of payments were first being made about 3200 BCE. The Code of Hammurabi, written on a clay tablet around 1700 BCE, describes the regulation of banking activity within the civilization (Armstrong); although still rudimentary, banking was well enough developed to justify laws governing banking operations.[nb 1] Later during the Achaemenid Empire (after 646 BCE),[7] further evidence is found of banking practices in the Mesopotamia region.[8][9][10][11][12][13][14][15]
Structural
[edit]By the 5th millennium BCE, the settlements of Sumer, such as Eridu, were formed around a central temple. In the fifth millennium, people began to build and live in the civilization of cities, providing a structure for the construction of institutions and establishments. Tell Brak and Uruk were two early urban settlements.[11][16][17][18][19]
Earliest forms of banking
[edit]Asia
[edit]Mesopotamia and Persia
[edit]Banking as an archaic activity (or quasi-banking[20][21]) is thought to have begun as early as the latter part of the 4th millennium BCE,[22] to the 3rd millennia BCE.[23][24]
Prior to the reign of Sargon I of Akkad (2335–2280 BCE[25]) the occurrence of trade was limited to the internal boundaries of each city-state of Babylon and the temple located at the centre of economic activity therein; trade at the time for citizens external to the city was forbidden.[16][26][27]
In Babylonia of 2000 BCE, people depositing gold were required to pay amounts as much as one sixtieth of the total deposited. Both the palaces and temple are known to have provided lending and issuing from the wealth they held—the palaces to a lesser extent. Such loans typically involved issuing seed-grain, with re-payment from the harvest. These basic social agreements were documented in clay tablets, with an agreement on interest accrual. The habit of depositing and storing of wealth in temples continued at least until 209 BCE, as evidenced by Antiochus III having ransacked or pillaged the temple of Aine in Ecbatana (Media) of gold and silver.[28][29][30][31][32][33][34][35]
More information comes from the code commissioned by Hammurabi, king of Babylon c. 1792–1750 BCE. Law 100 stipulated that repayment of a loan by a debtor to a creditor was to be on a schedule with a maturity date specified in written contractual terms.[36][37][38] Law 122 stipulated that a depositor of gold, silver, or other property must present all articles and a signed contract of bailment to a notary before depositing the articles with a banker, and Law 123 stipulated that a banker was discharged of any liability from a contract of bailment if the notary denied the existence of the contract. Law 124 stipulated that a depositor with a notarized contract of bailment was entitled to redeem the entirety of their deposit, and Law 125 stipulated that a banker was liable for replacement of deposits stolen while in their possession.[39][40][38]
Cuneiform records of the house of Egibi of Babylonia describe the family's financial activities as having occurred sometime after 1000 BCE and ending sometime during the reign of Darius I. These records suggest a "lending house" (Silver 2002), a family engaging in "professional banking..." (Dandamaev et al. 2004), and economic activities similar to modern deposit banking. Another interpretation is that the family's activities are better described as entrepreneurship rather than banking (Wunsch 2007). The Murashu family apparently took part in providing credit (Moshenskyi 2008).[41][42][43][44][45][46][47][48][49][50]
Asia Minor
[edit]From the fourth millennium previously agricultural settlements began administrative activities.[51][52][53][54]
The temple of Artemis at Ephesus was the largest depository of Asia. A pot hoard dated to 600 BCE was found in excavations by The British Museum during 1904. During the time of the cessation of the first Mithridatic war, the entire debt being held at the time was annulled by the council. Mark Antony is recorded to have stolen from the deposits on occasion. The temple served as a depository for Aristotle, Caesar, Dio Chrysostomus, Plautus, Plutarch, Strabo and Xenophon.[55][56][57][58][59][60][61]
The temple to Apollo in Didyma was constructed sometime in the 6th century. A large sum of gold was deposited within the treasury at the time by king Croesus.[62][63]
India
[edit]In ancient India there are evidences of loans from the Vedic period (beginning 1750 BCE). Later during the Maurya dynasty (321–185 BCE), an instrument called adesha was in use, which was an order on a banker desiring him to pay the money of the note to a third person, which corresponds to the definition of a bill of exchange as we understand it today. During the Buddhist period, there was considerable use of these instruments. Merchants in large towns gave letters of credit to one another.[64][65][66]
China
[edit]Main: History of banking in China
In ancient China, starting in the Qin dynasty (221–206 BCE), Chinese currency developed with the introduction of standardized coins that allowed easier trade across China, and led to development of letters of credit. These letters were issued by merchants who acted in ways that today we would understand as banks.[67]
Ancient Egypt
[edit]Some scholars suggest that the Egyptian grain-banking system became so well-developed that it was comparable to major modern banks, both in terms of its number of branches and employees, and in terms of the total volume of transactions. During the rule of the Greek Ptolemies, the granaries were transformed into a network of banks centered in Alexandria, where the main accounts from all of the Egyptian regional grain-banks were recorded. This became the site of one of the earliest known government central banks, and may have reached its peak with the assistance of Greek bankers.[68]
According to Muir (2009) there were two types of banks operating within Egypt: royal and private.[69] Documents made to show the banking of taxes were known as peptoken-records.[70]
Greece
[edit]Trapezitica is the first source documenting banking (de Soto – p. 41). The speeches of Demosthenes contain numerous references to the issuing of credit (Millett p. 5). Xenophon is credited to have made the first suggestion of the creation of an organisation known in the modern definition as a joint-stock bank in On Revenues written c. 353 BCE[71][72][73][74]
The city-states of Greece after the Persian Wars produced a government and culture sufficiently organized for the birth of a private citizenship and therefore an embryonic capitalist society, allowing for the separation of wealth from exclusive state ownership to the possibility of ownership by the individual.[75][76]
According to one source (Dandamaev et al.), trapezites were the first to trade using money, during the 5th century BCE, as opposed to earlier trade which occurred using forms of pre-money.[77]
Specific focus of funds
[edit]The earliest forms of storage utilized were the rudimentary money-boxes (ΘΗΣΑΥΡΌΣ[78]) which were made similar in form to the construction of a bee-hive, and were found for example in the Mycenae tombs of 1550–1500 BCE.[79][80][81][82][83][84][85]
Private and civic entities within ancient Grecian society, especially Greek temples, performed financial transactions. (Gilbart p. 3) The temples were the places where treasure was deposited for safe-keeping. The three temples thought the most important were the temple to Artemis in Ephesus, and temple of Hera within Samos, and within Delphi, the temple to Apollo. These consisted of deposits, currency exchange, validation of coinage, and loans.[71][73][86][87]
The first treasury to the Apollonian temple was built before the end of the 7th century BCE. A treasury of the temple was constructed by the city of Siphnos during the 6th century.[88][89][90]
Before the destruction by Persians during the 480 invasion, the Athenian Acropolis temple dedicated to Athena stored money; Pericles rebuilt a depository afterward contained within the Parthenon.[91]
During the reign of the Ptolemies, state depositories replaced temples as the location of security-deposits. Records exist to show this having occurred by the end of the reign of Ptolemy I (305–284).[92][93][94][95]
As the need for new buildings to house operations increased, construction of these places within the cities began around the courtyards of the agora (markets).[96]
Geographical focus of banking activities
[edit]Athens received the Delian league's treasury during 454.[97]
During the late 3rd and 2nd century BCE, the Aegean island of Delos became a prominent banking center.[98] During the 2nd century, there were for certain three banks and one temple depository within the city.[99]
Thirty-five Hellenistic cities had private banks during the 2nd century (Roberts – p. 130).[99]
Of the settlements of the Greco-Roman world of the 1st century CE, three were of pronounced wealth and centres of banking: Athens, Corinth and Patras.[100][101][102][103]
Loans
[edit]Many loans are recorded in writings from the classical age, although a very small proportion were provided by banks. Provision of these were likely an occurrence of Athens, with loans known to have been provided at some time at an annual interest of 12%. Within the boundaries of Athens, bankers' loans are recorded as having been issued on eleven occasions altogether (Bogaert 1968).[72][104][105]
Banks sometimes made loans available confidentially, which is, they provided funds without being publicly and openly known to have done so. In addition, they kept depositors' names confidential as well. This intermediation per se was known as dia tes trapazēs, translated from Latin as "God will trap you".[86]
A loan was made by a Temple of Athens to the state during 433–427 BCE.[106]
Rome
[edit]Roman banking activities were a crucial presence within temples. For instance the minting of coins occurred within temples, most importantly the Juno Moneta temple, though during the time of the Empire, public deposits gradually ceased to be held in temples, and instead were held in private depositories. Still, the Roman Empire inherited the mercantile practices from Greece (Parker).[75][92][107]
During 352 BCE a rudimentary public bank (known as dēmosía trápeza [108]) was formed, with the passing of a consular directive to form a commission of mensarii to deal with debt in the impoverished lower classes. Another source shows banking practices during 325 BCE when, on account of being in debt, the Plebeians were required to borrow money, so newly appointed quinqueviri mensarii were commissioned to provide services to those who had security to provide, in exchange for money from the public treasury. Another source (J. Andreau) has the shops of banking of Ancient Rome firstly opening in the public forums during the period 318 to 310 BCE.[109][110][111]
In early Ancient Rome deposit bankers were known as argentarii and at a later time (from the 2nd century CE onward) as nummularii (Andreau 1999 p. 2) or mensarii. The banking-houses were known as Taberae Argentarioe and Mensoe Numularioe. They would set up their stalls in the middle of enclosed courtyards called macella on a long bench called a bancu,[citation needed] from which the words banco and bank are derived.[112] As a money changer, the merchant at the bancu did not so much invest money as merely convert the foreign currency into the only legal tender in Rome—that of the Imperial Mint.[73][110][111][113]
Operations of banking within Roman society were known as officium argentarii. Statutes (125/126 CE) of the Empire described "letter from Caesar to Quietus" show rental monies to be collected from persons using land belonging to a temple and given to the temple treasurer, as decreed by Mettius Modestus, governor of Lycia and Pamphylia. A law, receptum argentarii, obliged a bank to pay its clients debts under guarantee.[114][115][116][117]
Cassius Dio advocated the establishment of a state bank, funded by the sale of all the properties owned at the time by the state.[118]
In the 4th century monopolies existed in Byzantium and in the city of Olbia in Sardinia.[119][120]
The Roman empire at some time formalized the administrative aspect of banking and instituted greater regulation of financial institutions and financial practices. Charging interest on loans and paying interest on deposits became more highly developed and competitive. The development of Roman banks was limited, however, by the Roman preference for cash transactions. During the reign of the Roman emperor Gallienus (260–268 CE), there was a temporary breakdown of the Roman banking system after the banks rejected the flakes of copper produced by his mints. With the ascent of Christianity, banking became subject to additional restrictions, as the charging of interest was seen as immoral. With the decrease in economic activity after the fall of Rome and Islamic invasions, banking likely temporarily ended in Europe and was not revived until Mediterranean trade commenced again in the 12th century.[121]
Religious restrictions on interest
[edit]Most early religious systems in the ancient Near East, and the secular codes arising from them, did not forbid usury. These societies regarded inanimate matter as alive, like plants, animals and people, and capable of reproducing itself. Hence if you lent 'food money', or monetary tokens of any kind, it was legitimate to charge interest.[122] Food money in the shape of olives, dates, seeds or animals was lent out as early as c. 5000 BCE, if not earlier. Among the Mesopotamians, Hittites, Phoenicians and Egyptians, interest was legal and often fixed by the state.[123]
Judaism
[edit]The Torah and later sections of the Hebrew Bible criticize interest-taking, but interpretations of the Biblical prohibition vary. One common understanding is that Jews are forbidden to charge interest upon loans made to other Jews, but obliged to charge interest on transactions with non-Jews. However, the Hebrew Bible itself gives numerous examples where this provision was evaded.
Deuteronomy 23:19 Thou shalt not lend upon interest to thy brother: interest of money, interest of victuals, interest of any thing that is lent upon interest. Deuteronomy 23:20 Unto a foreigner thou mayest lend upon interest; but unto thy brother thou shalt not lend upon interest; that the LORD thy God may bless thee in all that thou puttest thy hand unto, in the land whither thou goest in to possess it.[124]
In general, it was seen as advantageous to avoid debt at all, to avoid being bound to someone else. Debt was to be avoided and not used to finance consumption, except when in need. However, laws against usury were among many the prophets condemned the people for breaking.[126]
The interpretation that interest could be charged to non-Israelites would be used in the 14th century for Jews living within Christian societies in Europe to justify lending money for profit. This conveniently side stepped the rules against usury in both Judaism and Christianity, as Christians were not involved in the lending but were still free to take the loans.[citation needed]
Christianity
[edit]Originally, the charging of interest, known as usury, was banned by Christian churches. This included charging a fee for the use of money, such as at a bureau de change. However over time the charging of interest became acceptable due to the changing nature of money, and the term 'usury' came to be used for charging interest above the rate allowed by law.[citation needed] The notion of "Christian finance" refers to banking and financial activities that came into existence several centuries ago. Despite the prohibition of usury and the Church distrust against exchange activities (as opposed to production activities),[127] a number of operations of a banking or financial nature are in evidence in the activities of the Knights Templar (12th century), Mounts of Piety (appeared in 1462) and the Apostolic Chamber attached directly to the Vatican (money loans, guarantees, issuance of securities, investments, etc.)
The rise of Protestantism in the 16th century weakened Rome's influence, and its dictates against usury became irrelevant in some areas, freeing up the development of banking in Northern Europe. In the late 18th century, Protestant merchant families began to move into banking to an increasing degree, especially in trading countries such as the United Kingdom (Barings), Germany (Schroders, Berenbergs) and the Netherlands (Hope & Co., Gülcher & Mulder). At the same time, new types of financial activities broadened the scope of banking far beyond its origins. One school of thought attributes to Calvinism the setting of the stage for the later development of capitalism in northern Europe.[128] In this view, elements of Calvinism represented a revolt against the medieval condemnation of usury and, implicitly, of profit in general. Such a connection was advanced in influential works by R. H. Tawney (1880–1962) and by Max Weber (1864–1920). According to Weber, the Protestant work ethic was a force behind an unplanned and uncoordinated mass action that influenced the development of capitalism.
Rodney Stark propounds the theory that Christian rationality is the primary driver behind the success of capitalism and the Rise of the West.[129]
Islam
[edit]The Quran strictly prohibits lending money on Interest."Believers! Have fear of Allah and give up all outstanding interest if you do truly believe. But if you fail to do so then be warned of war from Allah and His Messenger. If you repent even now you have the right of the return of your capital; neither will you do wrong nor will you be wronged."(2:278-279) "O you who have believed, do not consume usury, doubled and multiplied, but fear Allah that you may be successful" (3:130) "and Allah has permitted trade and has forbidden interest" (2:275).
The Quran states that taking interest and making money through unethical means was prohibited for Muslims and in other communities in earlier times as well: "Because of the wrongdoing of the Jews We forbade them good things which were (before) made lawful unto them, and because of their much hindering from Allah's way, And of their taking usury when they were forbidden it, and of their devouring people's wealth by false pretenses, We have prepared for those of them who disbelieve a painful doom." (Al Quran – 4:160–161)
Riba is forbidden in Islamic economic jurisprudence (fiqh). Islamic jurists discuss two types of riba: an increase in capital with no services provided, which the Qur'an prohibits, and commodity exchanges in unequal quantities, which the Sunnah prohibits. Trade in promissory notes (e.g. fiat money and derivatives) is forbidden.[citation needed]
Despite the prohibition of charging interest, during the 20th century a number of developments took place that would lead to an Islamic banking model where no interest is charged but banks would still operate for profit. This was done through charging for loans in alternative ways such as through fees and using different methods of risk sharing and ownership models such as leasing.
Medieval Europe
[edit]The roots of modern banking are traceable to medieval and early Renaissance Europe, including Italy's Lombards in the 12th and 13th centuries, France's Cahorsins in the 13th century and in particular the rich Italian cities such as Florence, Venice, and Genoa.[130]
Emergence of merchant banks
[edit]The original banks were "merchant banks" that Italian grain merchants invented in the Middle Ages. As Lombardy merchants and bankers grew in wealth and credit based on the strength of the Lombard plains cereal crops, many displaced Jews fleeing Spanish persecution were attracted to the trade. They brought with them ancient practices from the Middle and Far East which had financed the trans-Asian silk routes. They applied these methods to finance grain production and distribution.
Barred from owning land in Italy, Jews entered the great trading piazzas and halls of Lombardy, alongside local traders, and set up their benches to trade in crops. They had one great advantage over the locals: Christians were strictly forbidden from the sin of usury, lending at interest, which was also condemned in the Islamic world, but with less strictness. The Jewish newcomers, on the other hand, could make high-risk loans to farmers against crops in the field without direct jurisdiction by the Church.[citation needed] They then began to advance payment against the future delivery of grain shipped to distant ports. In both cases they made a profit from the present discount against the future price. This two-handed trade was time-consuming and soon there arose a class of merchants who were trading grain debt instead of grain.
The Jewish trader performed both financing (credit) and underwriting (insurance) functions. Financing took the form of a crop loan at the beginning of the growing season, which allowed a farmer to cultivate his annual crop, with the associated expenses of seeding, growing, weeding, and harvesting. Underwriting in the form of crop, or commodity, insurance guaranteed the delivery of the crop to its buyer, typically a merchant wholesaler. In addition, traders performed the merchant function by making arrangements to supply the buyer with the crop through alternative sources—grain stores or alternate markets, for instance—in the event of crop failure. He could also keep the farmer (or other commodity producer) in business during a drought or other crop failure, through the issuance of crop (or commodity) insurance against the hazard of crop failure.
Merchant banking progressed from financing trade on one's own behalf to settling trades for others, and then to holding deposits for settlement of "billette" or notes written by the people who were still brokering the actual grain. And so the merchant's "benches" (bank is derived from the Italian for bench, banca, as in a counter) in the great grain markets became centres for holding money against a bill (billette, a note, a letter of formal exchange, later a bill of exchange and later still a cheque).
These deposited funds were intended to be held for the settlement of grain trades, but often were used for the bench's own trades in the meantime. The term bankrupt is a corruption of the Italian banca rotta, or broken bench, the symbolic ruin of an insolvent trader. The expression of "being broke" has a similar etymology.
Crusades
[edit]In the 12th century, the need to transfer large sums of money to finance the Crusades stimulated the re-emergence of banking in western Europe. In 1162, Henry II of England levied the first of a series of taxes to support the crusades. The Templar and Hospitaller Christian knights acted as Henry's bankers in the Holy Land. It is Pope Innocent II's decree that allowed the success of the Templar. This decree freed the Templar from paying tithe to the church and also granted them the ability to collect tithe for their own profit.[131] The Templars' rich land holdings across Europe also emerged during 1100–1300 as the beginning of Europe-wide banking. They took in local currency and issued demand notes redeemable at any of their castles across Europe, allowing movement of money without the usual risk of robbery while traveling. It is unclear if the Templar Knights used any hidden codes or encryptions to protect the notes given from any possible fraud.[132]
Discounting of interest
[edit]To circumvent the moral prohibition on usury, directly paying money for the use of money, the practice of discounting developed, in theory giving depositors an interest (part ownership) in the trades performed with their money. Similar methods had long been employed in Islamic banking.
Medieval trade fairs, such as the one in Hamburg, contributed to the growth of banking[when?] in a curious way: moneychangers issued documents redeemable at other fairs, in exchange for hard currency. These documents could be cashed at another fair in a different country or at a future fair in the same location. If redeemable at a future date, they would often be discounted by an amount comparable to a rate of interest. Eventually,[when?] these documents evolved into bills of exchange, which could be redeemed at any office of the issuing banker. These bills made it possible to transfer large sums of money without the complications of hauling large chests of gold protected by armed guards.
Italian bankers
[edit]The Republic of Venice, sometimes mistakenly credited with establishing a Bank of Venice in the 12th century, did not formally create a public bank until 1587. However in the 13th and 14th centuries its Grain Office did a banking business that included both deposits and lending.[133] The Republic's system of transferable public debt has also been identified as an important contribution to the development of banking.[134]
In the middle of the 13th century, groups of Christians, particularly the Italian Lombards and French Cahorsins, invented legal loopholes to get around the ban on Christian usury;[135] for example, one method of effecting a loan with interest was to offer money without interest, but also require that the loan be insured against possible loss or injury, and/or delays in repayment (see contractum trinius).[135] The Christians utilizing these legal loopholes became known as the pope's usurers, and reduced the importance of the Jews to European monarchs.[135] Later in the Middle Ages, a distinction evolved between consumable necessities such as food and fuel versus durable goods, with usury permitted on loans that involved the latter.[135]
The most powerful banking families came from Florence, including the Acciaiuoli, Mozzi,[136] Bardi and Peruzzi families, which established branches in many other parts of Europe.[1] Probably the most famous was the Medici bank, set up by Giovanni di Bicci de' Medici in 1397 [2] and continuing until 1494.[137] The oldest banking firm in current operation is Banca Monte dei Paschi di Siena S.p.A. (BMPS).
By the later Middle Ages, Christian merchants who lent money with interest gained ecclesiastical sanction, and Jews lost their privileged position as money-lenders.[135] Italian bankers would take their place, and by 1327, Avignon had 43 branches of Italian banking houses. In 1347, Edward III of England defaulted on loans. Later there was the bankruptcy of the Bardi (1343[136]) and Peruzzi (1346[136]). The accompanying growth of Italian banking in France was the start of the Lombard moneychangers in Europe, who moved from city to city along the busy pilgrim routes important for trade. Key cities in this period were Cahors, the birthplace of Pope John XXII, and Figeac.
After 1400, the political turned somewhat against the Italian bankers. In 1401 King Martin I of Aragon had some of them expelled. In 1403, Henry IV of England prohibited them from taking profits in his kingdom. In 1409, Flanders imprisoned and then expelled Genoese bankers. In 1410, all Italian merchants were expelled from Paris. In 1407, the Bank of Saint George,[138] the first state bank of deposit,[98][139] was founded in Genoa and was to dominate business in the Mediterranean.[98]
15th–17th centuries – Expansion
[edit]Italy
[edit]Between 1527 and 1572 a number of important banking family groups arose from the Genoese Republic in northern Italy, such as the Grimaldi, Spinola and Pallavicino families, who were especially influential and wealthy, the Doria, although perhaps less influential, and the Pinelli and the Lomellini.[140][141]
Spain and the Ottoman Empire
[edit]In 1401 the magistrates of Barcelona, then the capital of the Principality of Catalonia, established in the city the first replication of the Venetian model of exchange and deposit, the Taula de canvi de Barcelona or Table of Exchange, considered to be the first public bank of Europe.[142][143][144]
Halil Inalcik suggests that, in the 16th century, Marrano Jews (Doña Gracia from the House of Mendes) fleeing from Iberia introduced the techniques of European capitalism, banking and even the mercantilist concept of state economy to the Ottoman Empire.[145] In the 16th century, the leading financiers in Istanbul were Greeks and Jews. Many of the Jewish financiers were Marranos who had fled from Iberia during the period leading up to the expulsion of Jews from Spain. Some of these families brought great fortunes with them.[146] The most notable of the Jewish banking families in the 16th-century Ottoman Empire was the Marrano banking house of Mendes, which moved to Istanbul in 1552, under the protection of Sultan Suleiman the Magnificent. When Alvaro Mendes arrived in Istanbul in 1588, he is reported to have brought with him 85,000 gold ducats.[147] The Mendes family soon acquired a dominating position in the state finances of the Ottoman Empire and in commerce with Europe.[148]
They thrived in Baghdad during the 18th and 19th centuries under Ottoman rule, performing critical commercial functions such as moneylending and banking.[149] Like the Armenians, the Jews could engage in necessary commercial activities, such as moneylending and banking, that were proscribed for Muslims under Islamic law.
Court Jew
[edit]Court Jews were Jewish bankers or businessmen who lent money and handled the finances of some of the Christian European noble houses, primarily in the 17th and 18th centuries.[150] Court Jews were precursors to the modern financier or Secretary of the Treasury.[150] Their jobs included raising revenues by tax farming, negotiating loans, master of the mint, creating new sources for revenue, floating debentures, devising new taxes, and supplying the military.[150][151] In addition, the court Jews acted as personal bankers for the nobility: They raised money to cover the noble's personal diplomacy and his extravagances.[151]
Court Jews were skilled administrators and businessmen who received privileges in return for their services. They were most commonly found in Germany, Holland, and Austria, but also in Denmark, England, Hungary, Italy, Poland, Lithuania, Portugal, and Spain.[152][153] According to Dimont, virtually every duchy, principality, and palatinate in the Holy Roman Empire had a court Jew.[150]
Germany
[edit]In the southern German realm, two great banking families emerged in the 15th century, the Fuggers and the Welsers. They came to control much of the European economy and to dominate international high finance in the 16th century.[154][155][156] The Fuggers built the first German social housing area for the poor in Augsburg, the Fuggerei. It still exists, but not the original Fugger Bank which lasted from 1487 to 1657.
Dutch bankers played a central role in establishing banking in the northern German city states. Berenberg Bank is the oldest bank in Germany and the world's second oldest, established in 1590 by Dutch brothers Hans and Paul Berenberg in Hamburg. The bank is still owned by the Berenberg dynasty.[157]
Netherlands
[edit]In the 16th and 17th century, precious metals from the New World, Gold Coast, Japan and other locales were being imported into Europe, with corresponding price increases. Thanks to the free coinage,[clarification needed] the Bank of Amsterdam, and the heightened trade and commerce, the Netherlands attracted even more coin and bullion to be deposited in their banks. The concepts of fractional-reserve banking and payment systems were further developed and spread to England and elsewhere.[158]
England
[edit]In the City of London there were no banking houses operating in a manner recognized as so today until the 17th century,[159][160] although the London Royal Exchange was established in 1565.
17th–19th centuries – The emergence of modern banking
[edit]By the end of the 16th century and during the 17th, the traditional banking functions of accepting deposits, moneylending, money changing, and transferring funds were combined with the issuance of bank debt that served as a substitute for gold and silver coins.
New banking practices promoted commercial and industrial growth by providing a safe and convenient means of payment and a money supply more responsive to commercial needs, as well as by "discounting" business debt. By the end of the 17th century, banking was also becoming important for the funding requirements of the combative European states. This would lead on to government regulations and the first central banks. The success of the new banking techniques and practices in Amsterdam and London helped spread the concepts and ideas elsewhere in Europe.
Goldsmiths of London
[edit]Modern banking practice, including fractional reserve banking and the issue of banknotes, emerged in the 17th century. At the time, wealthy merchants began to store their gold with the goldsmiths of London, who possessed private vaults and charged a fee for their service. In exchange for each deposit of precious metal, the goldsmiths issued receipts certifying the quantity and purity of the metal they held as a bailee; these receipts could not be assigned, only the original depositor could collect the stored goods.
Gradually the goldsmiths began to lend the money out on behalf of the depositor, which led to the development of modern banking practices; promissory notes (which evolved into banknotes) were issued for money deposited as a loan to the goldsmith.[161]
These practices created a new kind of "money" that was actually debt, that is, goldsmiths' debt rather than silver or gold coin, a commodity that had been regulated and controlled by the monarchy. This development required the acceptance in trade of the goldsmiths' promissory notes, payable on demand. Acceptance in turn required a general belief that coin would be available; and a fractional reserve normally served this purpose. Acceptance also required that the holders of debt be able to legally enforce an unconditional right to payment; it required that the notes (as well as drafts) be negotiable instruments. The concept of negotiability had emerged in fits and starts in European money markets, but it was well developed by the 17th century. Nevertheless, an Act of Parliament was required in the early 18th century (1704) to overrule court decisions holding that the goldsmiths' notes, despite the "customs of merchants", were not negotiable.[162]
The modern bank
[edit]In 1695, the Bank of England became one of the first banks to issue banknotes, the first being the short-lived banknotes issued by Stockholms Banco in 1661.[163][164] Initially, these were hand-written and issued on deposit or as a loan, and promised to pay the bearer the value of the note on demand in specie. By 1745, standardized printed notes ranging from £20 to £1,000 were being issued. Fully printed notes that did not require the name of the payee and the cashier's signature first appeared in 1855.[165]
In the 18th century, services offered by banks increased. Clearing facilities, security investments, cheques and overdraft protections were introduced. Cheques had been used since the 1600s in England and banks settled payments by direct courier to the issuing bank. Around 1770, they began meeting in a central location, and by the 1800s a dedicated space was established, known as a bankers' clearing house. The method used by the London clearing house involved each bank paying cash to an inspector and then being paid cash by the inspector at the end of each day. The first overdraft facility was set up in 1728 by the Royal Bank of Scotland.[166]
The number of banks increased during the Industrial Revolution and the growing international trade, especially in London. At the same time, new types of financial activities broadened the scope of banking. The merchant-banking families dealt in everything from underwriting bonds to originating foreign loans. These new "merchant banks" facilitated trade growth, profiting from England's emerging dominance in seaborne shipping. Two immigrant families, Rothschild and Baring, established merchant banking firms in London in the late 18th century and came to dominate world banking in the next century.
A great impetus to country banking came in 1797 when, with England threatened by war, the Bank of England suspended cash payments. A handful of Frenchmen landed in Pembrokeshire, causing a panic. Shortly after this incident, Parliament authorised the Bank of England and country bankers to issue notes of low denomination.
Chinese banking
[edit]During the Qing dynasty, the private nationwide financial system in China was first developed by the Shanxi merchants, with the creation of so-called "draft banks". The first draft bank Rishengchang was created around 1823 in Pingyao. Some large draft banks had branches in Russia, Mongolia and Japan to facilitate international trade. Throughout the 19th century, the central Shanxi region became the de facto financial centre of Qing China.
With the fall of the Qing dynasty, the financial centers gradually shifted to Shanghai, with western-style modern banks flourishing. Today, the financial centres in China are Hong Kong, Beijing, Shanghai and Shenzhen.
Japanese banking
[edit]In 1868, the Meiji government attempted to formulate a functioning banking system, which continued until some time during 1881. They emulated French models. The Imperial mint began using imported machines from Britain in the early years of the Meiji period.[167][168]
Masayoshi Matsukata was a formative figure of a later banking initiative.[167]
Development of central banking
[edit]The Taula de canvi de Barcelona, established in 1401, is the first example of municipal, mostly public banks which pioneered central banking on a limited scale. It was soon emulated by the Bank of Saint George in the Republic of Genoa, first established in 1407, and significantly later by the Banco del Giro in the Republic of Venice and by a network of institutions in Naples that later consolidated into Banco di Napoli. Notable municipal central banks were established in the early 17th century in leading northwestern European commercial centers, namely the Bank of Amsterdam in 1609 and the Hamburger Bank in 1619.[169] These institutions offered a public infrastructure for cashless international payments.[170]
The first national (as opposed to municipal) central bank was the Swedish central bank, known since 1866 as Sveriges Riksbank, founded in Stockholm in 1664 from the remains of the failed Stockholms Banco.[171] A generation later, the establishment of the Bank of England was devised by Charles Montagu, 1st Earl of Halifax, following a 1691 proposal by William Paterson.[172] A royal charter was granted on 27 July 1694 through the passage of the Tonnage Act.[173] The bank was given exclusive possession of the government's balances, and was the only limited-liability corporation allowed to issue banknotes.[174][page needed] In the early 18th century, a major experiment in national central banking failed in France with John Law's Banque Royale in 1720-1721. A comparatively more successful attempt was the Bank of Spain established by King Charles III in 1782. The Russian Assignation Bank, established in 1769 by Catherine the Great, was an outlier from the general pattern of early national central banks in that it was directly owned by the Imperial Russian government, rather than private individual shareholders. In the nascent United States, Alexander Hamilton, as Secretary of the Treasury in the 1790s, set up the First Bank of the United States despite heavy opposition from Jeffersonian Republicans.[175]
Central banks were established in many European countries during the 19th century.[176][177] Napoleon created the Banque de France in 1800, in order to stabilize and develop the French economy and to improve the financing of his wars.[178] The Bank of France remained the most important Continental European central bank throughout the 19th century.[citation needed] The Bank of Finland was founded in 1812, soon after Finland had been taken over from Sweden by Russia to become a grand duchy.[179] Simultaneously, a quasi-central banking role was played by a small group of powerful family-run banking networks, typified by the House of Rothschild, with branches in major cities across Europe, as well as Hottinguer in Switzerland and Oppenheim in Germany.[180][181]
The 19th and early 20th centuries central banks in most of Europe and Japan developed under the international gold standard. Free banking or currency boards were common at the time.[citation needed] Problems with collapses of banks during downturns, however, led to wider support for central banks in those nations which did not as yet possess them, for example in Australia.[citation needed] In the United States, the role of a central bank had been ended in the so-called Bank War of the 1830s by President Andrew Jackson.[182] In 1913, the U.S. created the Federal Reserve System through the passing of The Federal Reserve Act.[183]
Following World War I, the Economic and Financial Organization (EFO) of the League of Nations, influenced by the ideas of Montagu Norman and other leading policymakers and economists of the time, took an active role to promote the independence of central bank, a key component of the economic orthodoxy the EFO fostered at the Brussels Conference (1920). The EFO thus directed the creation of the Oesterreichische Nationalbank in Austria, Hungarian National Bank, Bank of Danzig, and Bank of Greece, as well as comprehensive reforms of the Bulgarian National Bank and Bank of Estonia. Similar ideas were emulated in other newly independent European countries, e.g. for the National Bank of Czechoslovakia.[184]
By 1935, the only significant independent nation that did not possess a central bank was Brazil, which subsequently developed a precursor thereto in 1945 and the present Central Bank of Brazil twenty years later. After gaining independence, numerous African and Asian countries also established central banks or monetary unions. The Reserve Bank of India, which had been established during British colonial rule as a private company, was nationalized in 1949 following India's independence. By the early 21st century, most of the world's countries had a national central bank set up as a public sector institution, albeit with widely varying degrees of independence.
Rothschilds
[edit]The Rothschild family pioneered international finance in the early 19th century. The family provided loans to the Bank of England and purchased government bonds in the stock markets.[185] Their wealth has been estimated to possibly be the most in modern history.[186] In 1804, Nathan Mayer Rothschild began to deal on the London stock exchange in financial instruments such as foreign bills and government securities. From 1809 Rothschild began to deal in gold bullion, and developed this as a cornerstone of his business. From 1811 on, in negotiation with Commissary-General John Charles Herries, he undertook to transfer money to pay Wellington's troops, on campaign in Portugal and Spain against Napoleon, and later to make subsidy payments to British allies when these organized new troops after Napoleon's disastrous Russian campaign. His four brothers helped co-ordinate activities across the continent, and the family developed a network of agents, shippers and couriers to transport gold—and information—across Europe. This private intelligence service enabled Nathan to receive in London the news of Wellington's victory at the Battle of Waterloo a full day ahead of the government's official messengers.[187]
The Rothschild family were instrumental in supporting railway systems across the world and in complex government financing for projects such as the Suez Canal. The family bought up a large proportion of the property in Mayfair, London. Major businesses directly founded by Rothschild family capital include Alliance Assurance (1824) (now Royal & SunAlliance); Chemin de Fer du Nord (1845); Rio Tinto Group (1873); Société Le Nickel (1880) (now Eramet); and Imétal (1962) (now Imerys). The Rothschilds financed the founding of De Beers, as well as Cecil Rhodes on his expeditions in Africa and the creation of the colony of Rhodesia.[188]
The Japanese government approached the London and Paris families for funding during the Russo-Japanese War. The London consortium's issue of Japanese war bonds would total £11.5 million (at 1907 currency rates).[189]
From 1919 to 2004 the Rothschilds' Bank in London played a role as place of the gold fixing.
Napoleonic wars and Paris
[edit]Napoleon III had the goal of overtaking London to make Paris the premier financial center of the world, but the war in 1870 reduced the range of Parisian financial influence.[190] Paris had emerged as an international center of finance in the mid-19th century second only to London.[191] It had a strong national bank and numerous aggressive private banks that financed projects all across Europe and the expanding French Empire.
One key development was setting up one of the main branches of the Rothschild family. In 1812, James Mayer Rothschild arrived in Paris from Frankfurt, and set up the bank "De Rothschild Frères".[192] This bank funded Napoleon's return from Elba and became one of the leading banks in European finance. The Rothschild banking family of France funded France's major wars and colonial expansion.[193] The Banque de France, founded in 1796 helped resolve the financial crisis of 1848 and emerged as a powerful central bank. The Comptoir National d'Escompte de Paris (CNEP) was established during the financial crisis and the republican revolution of 1848. Its innovations included both private and public sources in funding large projects, and the creation of a network of local offices to reach a much larger pool of depositors.
Building societies
[edit]Building societies were established as financial institutions owned by their members as mutual organizations. The origins of the building society as an institution lie in late-18th century Birmingham—a town which was undergoing rapid economic and physical expansion driven by a multiplicity of small metalworking firms, whose many highly skilled and prosperous owners readily invested in property.[194]
Many of the early building societies were based in taverns or coffeehouses, which had become the focus for a network of clubs and societies for co-operation and the exchange of ideas among Birmingham's highly active citizenry as part of the movement known as the Midlands Enlightenment.[195] The first building society to be established was Ketley's Building Society, founded by Richard Ketley, the landlord of the Golden Cross inn, in 1775.[196]
Members of Ketley's society paid a monthly subscription to a central pool of funds which was used to finance the building of houses for members, which in turn acted as collateral to attract further funding to the society, enabling further construction.[197][198] The first outside the English Midlands was established in Leeds in 1785.[199]
Mutual savings bank
[edit]Mutual savings banks also emerged at that time, as financial institutions chartered by government, without capital stock, and owned by their members who subscribe to common funds. The institution most frequently identified as the first modern savings bank was the "Savings and Friendly Society" organized by the Reverend Henry Duncan in 1810, in Ruthwell, Scotland. Rev. Duncan established the small bank in order to encourage his working class congregation to develop thrift.
Another precursor to the modern savings bank originated in Germany, with Franz Hermann Schulze-Delitzsch and Friedrich Wilhelm Raiffeisen who developed cooperative banking models that led on to the credit union movement. The traditional banks had viewed poor and rural communities as unbankable because of very small, seasonal flows of cash and very limited human resources. In the history of credit unions the concepts of cooperative banking spread through northern Europe and onto the US at the turn of the 20th century under a wide range of different names.
Postal savings system
[edit]To provide depositors who did not have access to banks a safe, convenient method to save money and to promote saving among the poor, the postal savings system was introduced in Great Britain in 1861. It was vigorously supported by William Ewart Gladstone, then Chancellor of the Exchequer, who saw it as a cheap way to finance the public debt. At the time, banks were mainly in the cities and largely catered to wealthy customers. Rural citizens and the poor had no choice but to keep their funds at home or on their persons. The original Post Office Savings Bank was limited to deposits of £30 a year with a maximum balance of £150. Interest was paid at the rate of two and one-half percent per year on whole pounds in the account.
Similar institutions were created in a number of different countries in Europe, North America, and Japan. One example was in 1881 the Dutch government created the Rijkspostspaarbank (State post savings bank), a postal savings system to encourage workers to start saving. Four decades later they added the Postcheque and Girodienst services allowing working families to make payments via post offices in the Netherlands.
20th century
[edit]The first decade of the 20th century saw the Panic of 1907 in the US, which led to numerous runs on banks and became known as the bankers panic.
Great Depression
[edit]During the Crash of 1929 preceding the Great Depression, margin requirements were only 10%.[200] Brokerage firms, in other words, would lend $9 for every $1 an investor had deposited. When the market fell, brokers called in these loans, which could not be paid back. Banks began to fail as debtors defaulted on debt and depositors attempted to withdraw their deposits en masse, triggering multiple bank runs. Government guarantees and Federal Reserve banking regulations to prevent such panics were ineffective or not used. Bank failures led to the loss of billions of dollars in assets.[201] Outstanding debts became heavier, because prices and incomes fell by 20–50% but the debts remained at the same dollar amount. After the panic of 1929, and during the first 10 months of 1930, 744 US banks failed. By April 1933, around $7 billion in deposits had been frozen in failed banks or those left unlicensed after the March Bank Holiday.[202]
Bank failures snowballed as desperate bankers called in loans that borrowers did not have time or money to repay. With future profits looking poor, capital investment and construction slowed or completely ceased. In the face of bad loans and worsening future prospects, the surviving banks became even more conservative in their lending.[201] Banks built up their capital reserves and made fewer loans, which intensified deflationary pressures. A vicious cycle developed and the downward spiral accelerated. In all, over 9,000 banks failed during the 1930s.
In response, many countries significantly increased financial regulation. The U.S. established the Securities and Exchange Commission in 1933, and passed the Glass–Steagall Act, which separated investment banking and commercial banking. This was to avoid more risky investment banking activities from ever again causing commercial bank failures.
World Bank and the development of payment technology
[edit]During the post Second World War period and with the introduction of the Bretton Woods system in 1944, two organizations were created: the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank.[203] Encouraged by these institutions, commercial banks started to lend to sovereign states in the third world. This was at the same time as inflation started to rise in the west. The gold standard was eventually abandoned in 1971 and a number of the banks were caught out and became bankrupt due to third world country debt defaults.
This was also a time of increasing use of technology in retail banking. In 1959, banks agreed on a standard for machine readable characters (MICR) that was patented in the United States for use with cheques, which led to the first automated reader-sorter machines. In the 1960s, the first automated teller machines (ATM) or cash machines were developed and first machines started to appear by the end of the decade.[204] Banks started to become heavy investors in computer technology to automate much of the manual processing, which began a shift by banks from large clerical staffs to new automated systems. By the 1970s the first payment systems started to develop that would lead to electronic payment systems for both international and domestic payments. The international SWIFT payment network was established in 1973 and domestic payment systems were developed around the world by banks working together with governments.[205]
Deregulation and globalization
[edit]Global banking and capital market services proliferated during the 1980s after deregulation of financial markets in a number of countries. The 1986 'Big Bang' in London allowing banks to access capital markets in new ways, which led to significant changes to the way banks operated and accessed capital. It also started a trend where retail banks started to acquire investment banks and stock brokers creating universal banks that offered a wide range of banking services.[206] The trend also spread to the US after much of the Glass–Steagall Act was repealed in 1999 (during the Clinton Administration), this saw US retail banks embark on big rounds of mergers and acquisitions and also engage in investment banking activities.[207]
Financial services continued to grow through the 1980s and 1990s as a result of a great increase in demand from companies, governments, and financial institutions, but also because financial market conditions were buoyant and, on the whole, bullish. Interest rates in the United States declined from about 15% for two-year U.S. Treasury notes to about 5% during the 20-year period, and financial assets grew then at a rate approximately twice the rate of the world economy.
This period saw a significant internationalization of financial markets. The increase of U.S. Foreign investments from Japan not only provided the funds to corporations in the U.S., but also helped finance the federal government.
The dominance of U.S. financial markets was disappearing and there was an increasing interest in foreign stocks. The extraordinary growth of foreign financial markets results from both large increases in the pool of savings in foreign countries, such as Japan, and, especially, the deregulation of foreign financial markets, which enabled them to expand their activities. Thus, American corporations and banks started seeking investment opportunities abroad, prompting the development in the U.S. of mutual funds specializing in trading in foreign stock markets.[citation needed]
Such growing internationalization and opportunity in financial services changed the competitive landscape, as now many banks would demonstrate a preference for the "universal banking" model prevalent in Europe. Universal banks are free to engage in all forms of financial services, make investments in client companies, and function as much as possible as a "one-stop" supplier of both retail and wholesale financial services.[208]
21st century
[edit]The early 2000s were marked by consolidation of existing banks and entrance into the market of other financial intermediaries: non-bank financial institution. Large corporate players were beginning to find their way into the financial service community, offering competition to established banks. The main services offered included insurance, pension, mutual, money market and hedge funds, loans and credits and securities. Indeed, by the end of 2001 the market capitalisation of the world's 15 largest financial services providers included four non-banks.[citation needed]
The first decade of the 21st century saw the culmination of the technical innovation in banking over the previous 30 years and saw a major shift away from traditional banking to internet banking. Starting in 2015 developments such as open banking made it easier for third parties to access bank transaction data and introduced standard API and security models.
The process of financial innovation also advanced enormously in the first few decades of the 21st century, increasing the importance and profitability of nonbank finance. Such profitability priorly restricted to the non-banking industry, has prompted the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC) to encourage banks to explore other financial instruments, diversifying banks' business as well as improving banking economic health. Hence, as the distinct financial instruments are being explored and adopted by both the banking and non-banking industries, the distinction between different financial institutions is gradually vanishing. For example, in 2020, the OCC muddled the distinction between traditional banking and the cryptocurrency ecosystem when it published a number of interpretive letters clarifying national banks' ability to custody cryptocurrency and provide banking services to cryptocurrency companies,[209] as well as use blockchain innovations like stablecoins as settlement infrastructure.[210] In addition, in 2021, the OCC granted its first federal banking charter to Anchorage Digital, a digital asset platform for institutions.[211]
2007–2008 financial crisis
[edit]The 2007–2008 financial crisis caused significant stress on banks around the world. The failure of a large number of major banks resulted in government bail-outs. The collapse and fire sale of Bear Stearns to JPMorgan Chase in March 2008 and the collapse of Lehman Brothers in September that same year led to a credit crunch and global banking crises. In response governments around the world bailed-out, nationalised or arranged fire sales for a large number of major banks. Starting with the Irish government on 29 September 2008,[212] governments around the world provided wholesale guarantees to underwriting banks to avoid panic of systemic failure to the whole banking system. These events spawned the term 'too big to fail' and resulted in a lot of discussion about the moral hazard of these actions.
Major events in the history of banking
[edit]- 1100 – Knights Templar run earliest European wide/Mideast banking until the 14th century.
- 1397 – The Medici Bank of Florence is established in Italy and operates until 1494.
- 1542 – The Great Debasement, the English Crown's policy of coin debasement during the reigns of Henry VIII and Edward VI.
- 1553 – The first joint-stock company, the Company of Merchant Adventurers to New Lands, was chartered in London.
- 1602 – The Amsterdam Stock Exchange was established by the Dutch East India Company for dealings in its printed stocks and bonds.
- 1609 – The Amsterdamsche Wisselbank (Amsterdam Exchange Bank) was founded.
- 1656 – The first European bank to use banknotes opened in Sweden for private clients, in 1668 the institution converted to a public bank.[213][214][215]
- 1690s – The Massachusetts Bay Colony was the first of the Thirteen Colonies to issue permanently circulating banknotes.
- 1694 – The Bank of England was founded to supply money to the English King.
- 1695 – The Parliament of Scotland created the Bank of Scotland.
- 1716 – John Law opened Banque Générale in France.
- 1717 – Master of the Royal Mint Sir Isaac Newton established a new mint ratio between silver and gold that had the effect of driving silver out of circulation (bimetalism) and putting Britain on a gold standard.
- 1720 – The South Sea Bubble and John Law's Mississippi Scheme failure caused a European financial crisis and forced many bankers out of business.
- 1775 – The first building society, Ketley's Building Society, was established in Birmingham, England.
- 1782 – The Bank of North America opened.[216]
- 1791 – The First Bank of the United States was chartered by the United States Congress for 20 years.
- 1800 – The Rothschild family establishes European wide banking.
- 1800 – Napoleon Bonaparte founds the Bank of France on 18 January.[217][218]
- 1811 – The Senate tied on a vote to renew the charter of the First Bank of the United States charter. Vice President George Clinton broke the tie and voted against renewal, and the bank was dissolved.
- 1816 – The Second Bank of the United States was chartered for 20 years. Difficulties financing the government during and after the War of 1812 overcame the resistance to central banking that lead to the expiration of the First Bank of the United States' charter five years earlier.
- 1817 – The New York Stock Exchange Board was established.[216]
- 1818 – The first savings bank of Paris was established.[218]
- 1825 – Panic of 1825 in which 70 UK banks fail
- 1862 – To finance the American Civil War, the federal government under U.S. President Abraham Lincoln issued legal tender paper money, called "greenbacks".
- 1874 – The Specie Payment Resumption Act was passed provided for the redemption of United States paper currency, in gold, beginning in 1879.
- 1913 – The Federal Reserve Act created the Federal Reserve System, the central banking system of the United States, and granted it the legal authority to issue legal tender.
- 1930–33 – In the wake of the Wall Street Crash of 1929, 9,000 banks close, wiping out one third of the money supply in the United States.[219]
- 1933 – Executive Order 6102 signed by U.S. President Franklin D. Roosevelt forbade ownership of gold coin, gold bullion, and gold certificates by US citizens beyond a certain amount, effectively ending the convertibility of US dollars into gold.
- 1971 – The Nixon Shock was a series of economic measures taken by U.S. President Richard Nixon which canceled the direct convertibility of the United States dollar to gold by foreign nations. This essentially ended the existing Bretton Woods system of international financial exchange.
- 1986 – The "Big Bang" (deregulation of London financial markets) served as a catalyst to reaffirm London's position as a global centre of world banking.
- 2007 – Start of the 2007–2008 financial crisis including a credit crunch that led to the failure and bail-out of a large number of the world's biggest banks.
- 2008 – Washington Mutual collapses, the largest bank failure in history up to that point.
See also
[edit]References
[edit]Footnotes
[edit]- ^ The word "bank" reflects the origins of banking in temples. According to the famous passage from the New Testament, when Christ drove the money changers out of the temple in Jerusalem, he overturned their tables. Matthew 21.12. In Greece, bankers were known as trapezitai, a name derived from the tables where they sat. Similarly, the English word bank comes from the Italian banca, for bench or counter.
Citations
[edit]- ^ a b Hoggson, N. F. (1926) Banking Through the Ages, New York, Dodd, Mead & Company.
- ^ a b Goldthwaite, R. A. Banks, Places and Entrepreneurs in Renaissance Florence, (1995)
- ^ Boland, Vincent (12 June 2009). "Modern dilemma for world's oldest bank". Financial Times. Retrieved 23 February 2010.
- ^ R Marks was Richard and Billie Deihl Professor of History at Whittier College during 2000 (7 December 2006). The Origins of the Modern World: Fate and Fortune in the Rise of the West. Rowman & Littlefield, 7 December 2006. ISBN 9781461700005. Retrieved 1 June 2012.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list (link) - ^ Rondo E. Cameron (1993). A Concise Economic History of the World: From Paleolithic Times to the Present. Oxford University Press, 11 March 1993. ISBN 9780195074451. Retrieved 1 June 2012.
- ^ Ian Hodder – Religion in the Emergence of Civilization: Çatalhöyük as a Case Study Cambridge University Press, 30 August 2010 Retrieved 25 June 2012
- ^ MA Dandamaev – A Political History of the Achaemenid Empire BRILL, 1989 Retrieved 15 July 2012
- ^ Mario Liverani (4 December 2013). The Ancient Near East: History, Society and Economy. Routledge, 4 December 2013. ISBN 978-1134750849. Retrieved 12 February 2015. (p. 76 – "record-keeping & bulla"
- ^ A Robinson (5 April 2010). Writing and Script: A Very Short Introduction. Oxford University Press, 1 October 2009. ISBN 978-0199567782. Retrieved 8 June 2012.
- ^ H J Nissen; P Damerow; R K Englund (1993). Archaic bookkeeping. University of Chicago Press, 1993. ISBN 0226586596. Retrieved 8 June 2012.
- ^ a b M Liverani. Uruk: the first city. Translated by Z Bahrani; M Van de Mieroop. Equinox, 2006.
- ^ A Kuhrt (1995). The Ancient Near East, C. 3000–330 BC, Volume 1. Routledge, 1995. ISBN 0415167639. Retrieved 16 June 2012.
- ^ B Teissier (1 January 1984). Ancient Near Eastern Cylinder Seals from the Marcopoli Collection. University of California Press, 1984. ISBN 0520049276. Retrieved 16 June 2012.
- ^ H Williams (5 April 2010). Building Type Basics for Banks and Financial Institutions. John Wiley & Sons, 5 April 2010. ISBN 978-0470278628. Retrieved 8 June 2012.
- ^ D Schmandt-Besserat – Counting to Cuneiform University of Texas Press, 1992 ISBN 0292707835 Retrieved 8 June 2012
- ^ a b Moorey, P R S (1999). Ancient Mesopotamia :Materials and Industries The Archaeological Evidence. Eisenbrauns, 1 November 1999. ISBN 1575060426. Retrieved 8 June 2012.
- ^ P Watson – The Great Divide: History and Human Nature in the Old World and the New Hachette UK, 12 January 2012 -Retrieved 9 June 2012
- ^ Brian M. Fagan. World prehistory: a brief introduction. Prentice Hall, 2002.
- ^ Ur, Jason A. 2007 Early Mesopotamian urbanism: a new view from the North. Antiquity 81(313): 585–600. – [1] Retrieved 1 July 2012
- ^ M. Chahin – The Kingdom of Armenia: A History Routledge, 2001 ISBN 0700714529
- ^ ME Stevens Temples, Tithes, and Taxes: The Temple and the Economic Life of Ancient Israel Baker Academic, 2006 ISBN 0801047773
- ^ N Luhmann – Risk: A Sociological Theory Transaction Publishers, 2005 ISBN 0202307646 (p. 181)
- ^ Davies, R; Davies, G. A History of Money from Ancient Times to the Present Day. Cardiff: University of Wales Press, 1996.
- ^ naissance de la banque universalis.fr Accessed 15 September 2018
- ^ Chahin, M. – Before the Greeks James Clarke & Co., 1996 ISBN 0718829506 Retrieved 8 June 2012
- ^ Beaudreau, B C – World Trade iUniverse, 13 September 2004 ISBN 0595778445 Retrieved 8 June 2012
- ^ secondary references – [2] + [3] + [4] + [5]
- ^ GW Bromiley – International Standard Bible Encyclopedia: A-D Wm. B. Eerdmans Publishing, 13 February 1995 Retrieved 14 July 2012 ISBN 0802837816
- ^ the British Museum -image and information of a clay tablet showing practice from an earlier period Retrieved 9 April 2012
- ^ Orsingher, R Translated by D.S.Ault. Banks of the World. Walker and Company New York. Retrieved 9 April 2012.
- ^ G G Aperghis – The Seleukid Royal Economy: The Finances And Financial Administration Of The Seleukid Empire Cambridge University Press, 23 December 2004 ISBN 0521837073 Retrieved 10 June 2012
- ^ A Holm -translated by F. Clarke- The History of Greece from Its Commencement to the Close of the Independence of the Greek Nation, Vol. 4 of 4 Macmillan & Co 1898 – ISBN 1440041237 Retrieved 10 June 2012
- ^ C Anthon – A Classical Dictionary: Containing an Account of the Principal Proper Names Mentioned in Ancient Authors and Intended to Elucidate All the Important Points Connected with Geography, History, Biography, Mythology, and Fine Arts of the Greeks and Romans; Together with an Account of Coins, Weights, and Measures, with Tabular Values of the Same Harper & Brothers, 1855 – Retrieved 10 June 2012
- ^ W Smith – Dictionary of Greek and Roman geography, Volume 2 Walton & Maberly, 1857 – Retrieved 10 June 2012
- ^ Encyclopædia Britannica shows is "... Hamadān, Iran ..." – Retrieved 10 June 2012
- ^ Hammurabi (1903). "Code of Hammurabi, King of Babylon". Records of the Past. 2 (3). Translated by Sommer, Otto. Washington, DC: Records of the Past Exploration Society: 75. Retrieved 20 June 2021.
100. Anyone borrowing money shall ... his contract [for payment].
- ^ Hammurabi (1904). "Code of Hammurabi, King of Babylon" (PDF). Liberty Fund. Translated by Harper, Robert Francis (2nd ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. p. 35. Retrieved 20 June 2021.
§100. ...he shall write down ... returns to his merchant.
- ^ a b Hammurabi (1910). "Code of Hammurabi, King of Babylon". Avalon Project. Translated by King, Leonard William. New Haven, CT: Yale Law School. Retrieved 20 June 2021.
- ^ Hammurabi (1903). "Code of Hammurabi, King of Babylon". Records of the Past. 2 (3). Translated by Sommer, Otto. Washington, DC: Records of the Past Exploration Society: 77. Retrieved 20 June 2021.
122. If anyone entrusts to ... have committed an offence.
- ^ Hammurabi (1904). "Code of Hammurabi, King of Babylon" (PDF). Liberty Fund. Translated by Harper, Robert Francis (2nd ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. p. 43. Retrieved 20 June 2021.
§122. If a man give ... it from the thief.
- ^ R Rollinger, C Ulf, K Schnegg – Commerce and Monetary Systems in the Ancient World: Means of Transmission and Cultural Interaction : Proceedings of the Fifth Annual Symposium of the Assyrian and Babylonian Intellectual Heritage Project, Held in Innsbruck, Austria, 3–8 October 2002 M Silver – Modern Ancients Franz Steiner Verlag, 2004 Retrieved 10 July 2012 ISBN 3515083790
- ^ Gwendolyn Leick (ed.) – The Babylonian world C Wunsch – The Egibi Family Routledge 2007 Retrieved 10 July 2012 ISBN 1134261284
- ^ MA Dandamaev, VG Lukonin, PL Kohl – The Culture And Social Institutions Of Ancient Iran Cambridge University Press, 11 November 2004 Retrieved 10 July 2012 ISBN 0521611911
- ^ WI Davisson; JE Harper (1972). European Economic History. Appleton-Century-Crofts 1972. Retrieved 10 July 2012.
- ^ JP Nielsen – Sons and Descendants: A Social History of Kin Groups and Family Names in the Early Neo-Babylonian Period[permanent dead link] ProQuest, 2008 Retrieved 10 July 2012 ISBN 054956926X
- ^ OJ Thatcher – The Library of Original Sources: Volume I (The Ancient World) The Minerva Group, Inc., 30 June 2004 ISBN 141021401X translated by – TG Pinches Retrieved 10 July 2012
- ^ RN Frye – Handbuch der Altertumswissenschaft, Part 3, Volume 7 C.H.Beck, 1984 Retrieved 10 July 2012 ISBN 3406093973
- ^ S Moshenskyi – History of the Weksel Sergei Moshenskyi, 1 August 2008 Retrieved 10 July 2012 ISBN 1436306949
- ^ KR Nemet-Nejat –Daily Life in Ancient Mesopotamia Greenwood Publishing Group, 1998 Retrieved 10 July 2012 ISBN 0313294976
- ^ JA Thompson – The Bible and archaeology Paternoster Press, 1973 Retrieved 10 July 2012
- ^ S R Steadman, G McMahon – The Oxford Handbook of Ancient Anatolia: (10,000–323 Bce) Oxford University Press, 5 September 2011 ISBN 0195376145 Retrieved 25 June 2012
- ^ A. G. Sagona, Claudia Sagona – Archaeology at the North-east Anatolian Frontier, I.: An Historical Geography and a Field Survey of the Bayburt Province Peeters Publishers, 2004 ISBN 9042913908 Retrieved 25 June 2012
- ^ secondary – Luc-Normand Tellier Urban World History: An Economic and Geographical Perspective PUQ, 2009 ISBN 2760515885 Retrieved 25 June 2012
- ^ Catholic Encyclopedia New Advent Retrieved 25 June 2012
- ^ Walter Augustus Hawley (1918). Asia Minor. Elibron.com. ISBN 9781402185458. Retrieved 3 June 2012.
- ^ secondary – The British Museum Archived 4 November 2012 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved 3 June 2012
- ^ secondary – Dio Chrysostom Orations: 7, 12 and 36 (Edited by: D. A. Russell, St John's College, Oxford) Cambridge University Press 2012. Retrieved 3 June 2012
- ^ The British Museum Archived 5 February 2015 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved 3 June 2012
- ^ J. Murphy-O'Connor is Professor of the New Testament at the Ecole Biblique et Archeologique Francaise, Jerusalem (2008) (2008). St. Paul's Ephesus: Texts and Archaeology. Liturgical Press, 2008. ISBN 978-0814652596. Retrieved 3 June 2012.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list (link) - ^ secondary – N Hooke – The Roman History, from the Building of Rome to the Ruin of the Commonwealth, Volume 3 G. Hawkins, W. Strahan, 1770. Retrieved 3 June 2012
- ^ (p. 126) K Roberts →
- ^ J Freely (4 September 2004). The Western Shores Of Turkey: Discovering The Aegean And Mediterranean Coasts. Tauris Parke Paperbacks, 4 September 2004. ISBN 1850436185. Retrieved 15 June 2012.
- ^ The British Museum Archived 18 October 2015 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved 16 June 2012
- ^ C Gomez – Financial Markets Institutions And Financial Services Prentice-Hall 2008 Retrieved 11 July 2012 ISBN 8120335376
- ^ A Chavez Irapta, Et Al – Introduction to Asia: History, Culture, and Civilization Rex Bookstore, Inc., 2005 Retrieved 11 July 2012
- ^ "Evolution of Payment Systems in India =Reserve Bank of India". Archived from the original on 1 November 2014.
- ^ Wagel, Srinivas (1915). Chinese currency and banking.
- ^ "History of Money and Banking". Archived from the original on 25 February 2023. Retrieved 16 June 2020.
- ^ John Muir (2009). Life and Letters in the Ancient Greek World. Routledge. pp. 80–81. ISBN 978-1134166015.
- ^ Willy Clarysse; Dorothy J. Thompson (2006). Counting the People in Hellenistic Egypt: Historical Studies. Vol. 2. Cambridge University Press. p. 82. ISBN 9780521838399.
- ^ a b J Huerta de Soto – 1998 (translated by M.A.Stroup 2012) (2006). Money, Bank Credit, and Economic Cycles. Ludwig von Mises Institute. ISBN 1610161890. Retrieved 15 June 2012.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list (link) - ^ a b P Millett (9 May 2002). Lending and Borrowing in Ancient Athens. Cambridge University Press, 9 May 2002. ISBN 9780521893916. Retrieved 28 May 2012.
- ^ a b c J W Gilbart (1834). The history and principles of banking: The laws of the currency, etc. G. Bell, 1866. p. 9. Retrieved 9 April 2012.
Ancient banking.
- ^ J S Watson – Xenophon's Minor Works: Comprising the Agesilaus, Hiero, Oeconomicus, Banquet, Apology of Socrates, The Treatises on the Lacedaemonian and Athenian Governments, On Revenues of Athens, On Horsemanship, On the Duties of a Cavalry Officer, and On Hunting H.G. Bohn, 1857 – Retrieved 9 June 2012
- ^ a b Parker, W N (26 April 1991). Europe, America and the Wider World: Essays on the Economic History of Western Capitalism. Cambridge University Press, 26 April 1991. ISBN 0521274796. Archived from the original on 2 May 2006. Retrieved 8 June 2012.
- ^ R W Bulliet, P K Crossley, D R Headrick, S W Hirsch, L L Johnson – The Earth and Its Peoples: A Global History, Volume 1 Cengage Learning, 1 January 2010 Retrieved 8 June 2012
- ^ MA Dandamaev, VG Lukonin, PL Kohl – The Culture And Social Institutions Of Ancient Iran (p. 216) published by Cambridge University Press, 11 November 2004, ISBN 0521611911. Retrieved 7 September 2012
- ^ J Parkhurst – A Greek and English Lexicon to the New Testament: In which the Words and Phrases ... are Distinctly Explained, and the Meanings Assigned to Each Authorized by References to Passages of Scripture, and Frequently ... Confirmed by Citations from the Old Testament and from the Greek Writers. To this Work is Prefixed, a ... Greek Grammar ... J Davis 1898 – Retrieved 16 June 2012
- ^ J E Harrison – Epilegomena to the Study of Greek Religions and Themis a Study of the Social Origins of Greek Religion Kessinger Publishing, 1Jan 2003 ISBN 0766135284 Retrieved 16 June 2012
- ^ secondary – Varro et al – [6] Retrieved 16 June 2012
- ^ D Sacks, O Murray A Dictionary of the Ancient Greek World Oxford University Press, 6 February 1997 ISBN 0195112067 Retrieved 16 June 2012
- ^ secondary – The journal of the Royal Society of Antiquaries of Ireland 1894 " ...great treasury tombs probably range from this time to 1200..."
- ^ J E Harrison – Themis: A Study of the Social Origins of Greek Religion Cambridge University Press, 24 June 2010 ISBN 1108009492 Retrieved 16 June 2012
- ^ J A Harrill (1998). The Manumission of Slaves in Early Christianity. Mohr Siebeck. ISBN 3161469356. Retrieved 3 June 2012.
- ^ J Rüpke (25 March 2011). A Companion to Roman Religion. John Wiley & Sons. ISBN 978-1444341317. Retrieved 3 June 2012.
- ^ a b Edward E. Cohen (7 November 2011). Athenian Economy and Society: A Banking Perspective. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press 1992. ISBN 978-0-691-03609-0. Retrieved 5 September 2015.(and prior date)
- ^ W Smith, LLD, W Wayte, G. E. Marindin, Ed. A Dictionary of Greek and Roman Antiquities (1890). Perseus of Tufts University. Retrieved 15 June 2012.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link) - ^ R J A Talbert (1985). Atlas of Classical History. Taylor & Francis, 1985. ISBN 0709924488. Retrieved 15 June 2012.
- ^ secondary- [7] Retrieved 15 June 2012
- ^ F S Kleiner, H Gardner, C J Mamiya, Gardner's Art Through the Ages: A Global History, Enhanced Cengage Learning, 1 January 2010 ISBN 1439085781 Art Through The Ages: The Western Perspective ISBN 0495004782 Retrieved 15 June 2012
- ^ The Manumission of Slaves in Early Christianity By James Albert Harrill ISBN 3161469356 Retrieved 18 June 2012
- ^ a b H Temporini, W Haase (March 1978). Principat, Volume 8. Walter de Gruyter, 1977. ISBN 3110073374. Retrieved 3 June 2012.
- ^ W. V. Harris – The Monetary Systems of the Greeks and Romans Oxford University Press, 14 February 2008 ISBN 019161517X Retrieved 9 June 2012
- ^ A R David Handbook to Life in Ancient Egypt Oxford University Press, 28 October 1999 ISBN 0195132157 Retrieved 9 June 2012
- ^ J Tyldesley – Cleopatra: Last Queen of Egypt Profile Books, 26 May 2011 ISBN 1847650449 Retrieved 9 June 2012
- ^ M Gagarin, E Fantham – The Oxford Encyclopedia of Ancient Greece and Rome, Volume 1 Oxford University Press, 31 December 2009 Retrieved 17 July 2012 ISBN 0195170725
- ^ M Robertson- A Shorter History of Greek Art Cambridge University Press, 16 July 1981 ISBN 0521280842 Retrieved 18 June 2012
- ^ a b c J Braithwaite; P Drahos (February 2000). Global Business Regulation. Cambridge University Press, 1 February 2000. ISBN 0521784999. Retrieved 14 June 2012.
- ^ a b K Roberts (2011). The Origins of Business, Money, and Markets. Columbia University Press. ISBN 978-0231153263.
- ^ B R Braxton – The tyranny of resolution: I Corinthians 7:17–24 Society of Biblical Literature, 2000 Retrieved 14 June 2012
- ^ Sze-Kar Wan – Power in Weakness: Conflict and Rhetoric in Paul's Second Letter to the Corinthians Continuum International Publishing Group, 1 June 2000 ISBN 1563383152 Retrieved 14 June 2012
- ^ 2nd – [8] + [9] + [10] + [11]
- ^ Celebrating Common Prayer (Eastern Orthodox liturgics). Cassell & The European Province of the Society of Saint Francis. 1992. ISBN 0-264-67284-4.
- ^ DM Schaps – The Invention of Coinage and the Monetization of Ancient Greece University of Michigan Press, 2004 Retrieved 17 July 2012 ISBN 047211333X
- ^ Oesterreichische Nationalbank Archived 11 July 2012 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved 29 May 2012
- ^ S L Budin (p. 113)
- ^ Hudson, M. (26 February 2012). Entrepreneurs: From the Near Eastern Takeoff to the Roman Collapse within The Invention of Enterprise: Entrepreneurship from Ancient Mesopotamia to Modern Times. Princeton University Press, The Kauffman Foundation Series on Innovation and Entrepreneurship. p. 16. ISBN 978-1400833580. Retrieved 8 September 2015.
- ^ Brill Online Reference Works (October 2006). Trapezites. Koninklijke Brill NV. Retrieved 6 September 2015.
- ^ Piotr Niczyporuk – Mensarii, bankers acting for public and private benefit published by the Central European Journal of Social Sciences and Humanities 2011 | 24(37) | 105-115 Studies in Logic, Grammar and Rhetoric [Retrieved 30 August 2015] (please see also the same source linked in full here)
- ^ a b H D Macleod (1855). The theory and practice of banking, Volume 1. Longmans, Green, 1855. Retrieved 9 April 2012.
- ^ a b J Andreau (Director of Studies at the School of Higher study of the Social Sciences, Paris) (14 October 1999). Banking and Business in the Roman World. Cambridge University Press, 14 October 1999. ISBN 9780521389327. Retrieved 9 April 2012.
- ^ "bank | Origin and meaning of bank by Online Etymology Dictionary". www.etymonline.com. Retrieved 15 August 2020.
- ^ Matyszak, Philip (2007). Ancient Rome on Five Denarii a Day. New York: Thames & Hudson. p. 144. ISBN 978-0-500-05147-4.
- ^ Benke, N. (2012). "Gender and the Roman Law of Obligations". Obligations in Roman Law: Past, Present, and Future. Papers And Monographs Of The American Academy In Rome. Vol. 33. University of Michigan Press. p. 226. ISBN 978-0472118434.
- ^ A Chester Johnson, P Robinson Coleman-Norton, F Card Bourne – Ancient Roman Statutes: A Translation With Introduction, Commentary, Glossary, and Index The Lawbook Exchange, Ltd., 1 October 2003 Retrieved 9 July 2012 ISBN 1584772913
- ^ B Burrell ISBN 9004125787 p. 254
- ^ Zimmermann, Reinhard (1996). The Law of Obligations: Roman Foundations of the Civilian Tradition (reprint, revised ed.). Oxford University Press. p. 514. ISBN 019876426X.
- ^ Rostovtzeff, Michael Ivanovitch (1926). The Social & Economic History of the Roman Empire. Biblo & Tannen Publishers. p. 542. ISBN 0819621641.
- ^ Trade and Politics in Ancient Greece By Johannes Hasebroek (page 156) – Retrieved 14 July 2012
- ^ William Smith – Dictionary of Greek and Roman geography, Volume 2 Walton & Maberly, 1857 Retrieved 14 July 2012
- ^ Glasner, David (25 August 1989). Free Banking and Monetary Reform. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-36175-0.
- ^ Johnson cites Fritz E. Heichelcheim: An Ancient Economic History, 2 vols. (trans. Leiden 1965), i.104–566
- ^ Johnson, Paul: A History of the Jews (New York: HarperCollins Publishers, 1987) ISBN 0-06-091533-1. pp. 172–173
- ^ The Hebrew Bible in English according to the JPS 1917 Edition. http://www.mechon-mamre.org/e/et/et0523.htm
- ^ The references cited in the Passionary for this woodcut: 1 John 2:14–16, Matthew 10:8, and The Apology of the Augsburg Confession, Article 8, Of the Church Archived 15 July 2010 at the Wayback Machine
- ^ Examples of debt:1 Samuel 22:2, 2 Kings 4:1, Isaiah 50:1. Prophetic condemnation of usury: Ezekiel 22:12, Nehemiah 5:7 and 12:13. Cautions regarding debt: Prov 22:7, passim.
- ^ J. Le Goff, Marchands et banquiers au Moyen Âge, Puf Quadrige, 2011, p. 75
- ^ McKinnon, AM (2010). "Elective affinities of the Protestant ethic: Weber and the chemistry of capitalism" (PDF). Sociological Theory. 28 (1): 108–126. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9558.2009.01367.x. hdl:2164/3035. S2CID 144579790.
- ^ Stark, Rodney (2005). The Victory of Reason: How Christianity Led to Freedom, Capitalism, and Western Success. New York: Random House. ISBN 1-4000-6228-4.
- ^ "HISTORY OF BANKING". www.historyworld.net. Retrieved 22 March 2023.
- ^ Medievalists.net (22 August 2021). "Templar Banking: How to go from Donated Rags to Vast Riches". Medievalists.net. Retrieved 29 April 2024.
- ^ "The warrior monks who invented banking". BBC News. 30 January 2017. Retrieved 23 April 2024.
- ^ Ugolini, Stefano (2017). The Evolution of Central Banking: Theory and History.
- ^ Macleod, Henry Dunning (1856). The Theory and Practice of Banking. Vol. 1.
- ^ a b c d e Jewish Encyclopedia
- ^ a b c C Kleinhenz (2004). Medieval Italy: An Encyclopedia, Volume 1. Routledge, 2004. ISBN 0415939305. Retrieved 14 July 2012.
- ^ Charles P. Kindleberger (Professor of Economics Emeritus at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology – 2006) A Financial History of Western Europe Retrieved 17 May 2012
- ^ Freeman Hunt, William B. Dana (1859). Merchants' magazine and commercial review, Volume 40. F. Hunt, 1859.
- ^ 2nd – Holdsworth, W. S. -Early History of Banking 34 L. Q. Rev. 11 (1918) Retrieved 14 June 2012
- ^ C Duggan – A Concise History of Italy Cambridge University Press, 21 April 1994 Retrieved 14 July 2012 ISBN 0521408482
- ^ SB MacDonald, AL Gastmann – A History of Credit and Power in the Western World Transaction Publishers, 2004 Retrieved 14 July 2012 ISBN 0765808331
- ^ Thomas H. Goddard; Alexander Hamilton; George McDuffie (1831). A general history of the most prominent banks in Europe:particularly the banks of England and France; the rise and progress of the Bank of North America; a full history of the late and present Bank of the United States. H. C. Sleight, 1831. p. 10.
Venice bank subscription fund.
- ^ Thomas Henry Dyer The history of modern Europe: from the fall of Constantinople in 1453 to the war in the Crimea in 1857, Volume 2 John Murray, 1861 Retrieved 14 May 2012
- ^ La Vanguardia - El Banco de Barcelona financia el segundo viaje de Colón
- ^ Inalcik, Halil (1997). An economic and social history of the Ottoman Empire. Cambridge University Press. p. 213. ISBN 9780521574563.
- ^ Dumper, Michael; Stanley, Bruce E. (2007). Cities of the Middle East and North Africa: a historical encyclopedia. ABC-CLIO. p. 185. ISBN 9781576079195.
- ^ Inalcik, Halil; Quataert, Donald (1994). An economic and social history of the Ottoman Empire, 1300–1914. Cambridge University Press. p. 212. ISBN 9780521343152.
- ^ Bosworth, Clifford Edmund (2007). Historic cities of the Islamic world. BRILL. p. 207. ISBN 978-9004153882.
- ^ Black, Edwin (2004). Banking on Baghdad: inside Iraq's 7,000-year history of war, profit and conflict. John Wiley and Sons. p. 335. ISBN 9780471708957.
Under Ottoman rule, during the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, Jews continued to thrive, becoming part of the commercial and political ruling class. Like Christians, the Jews could engage in necessary commercial activities, such as moneylending and banking, that were proscribed for Moslems under Islamic law.
- ^ a b c d Dimont, Max (1962). Jews, God, and History. Signet Classic. pp. 273–4. ISBN 978-0-451-52940-4.
- ^ a b Kreftz, Gerald (1984). Jews and Money: The Myths and the Reality. Ticknor & Fields. p. 46. ISBN 978-0-89919-129-4.
- ^ Perry, p 131
- ^ Sombart, Werner (1913). The Jews and Modern Capitalism. pp. 53–7. ISBN 978-0-217-35289-5.
- ^ M Häberlein – The Fuggers of Augsburg: Pursuing Wealth and Honor in Renaissance Germany University of Virginia Press, 12 March 2012 Retrieved 14 July 2012 ISBN 0813932440
- ^ C Duggan
- ^ History World
- ^ Price Waterhouse Coopers Financial Year Book FYB, 2009
- ^ "Guide to Checks and Check Fraud" (PDF). Wachovia Bank. 2003. p. 4. Archived from the original (PDF) on 28 September 2011. Retrieved 13 June 2011.
- ^ James Walvin 17 February 2011 Slavery and the Building of Britain British Broadcasting Corporation Retrieved 19 April 2012
- ^ British Banking History Society A History of English Clearing Banks Archived 9 November 2016 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved 19 April 2012
- ^ Thus by the 19th century we find "[i]n ordinary cases of deposits of money with banking corporations, or bankers, the transaction amounts to a mere loan or mutuum, and the bank is to restore, not the same money, but an equivalent sum, whenever it is demanded." Joseph Story, Commentaries on the Law of Bailments (1832, p. 66) and "Money, when paid into a bank, ceases altogether to be the money of the principal (see Parker v. Marchant, 1 Phillips 360); it is then the money of the banker, who is bound to return an equivalent by paying a similar sum to that deposited with him when he is asked for it." Lord Chancellor Cottenham, Foley v Hill (1848) 2 HLC 28.
- ^ "Banking Origin and Development". Invest and Income. Archived from the original on 8 August 2011. Retrieved 26 July 2011.
{{cite web}}
: CS1 maint: unfit URL (link) - ^ "A History of British Banknotes".
- ^ Geisst, Charles R. (2005). Encyclopedia of American business history. New York. p. 39. ISBN 978-0-8160-4350-7.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link) - ^ "A brief history of banknotes". Retrieved 17 December 2013.
- ^ "A short history of overdrafts". eccount money. Archived from the original on 5 November 2013.
- ^ a b Norio Tamaki (2005). Japanese Banking: A History, 1859-1959. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521022330.
- ^ William M. Tsutsui (1999). Banking in Japan: The evolution of Japanese banking, 1868-1952 (p. xvi). published by Taylor & Francis 1999, 255 pages, Routledge library of modern Japan. ISBN 9780415170123. Retrieved 13 September 2015.
- ^ Quinn, Stephen; Roberds, William (2006), "An Economic Explanation of the Early Bank of Amsterdam, Debasement, Bills of Exchange, and the Emergence of the First Central Bank" Archived 3 May 2011 at the Wayback Machine, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Working Paper 2006–13
- ^ Collins, Christopher. The Oxford Encyclopedia of Economic History, Volume 3. Banking: Middle Ages and Early Modern Period, Oxford University Press, 2012, p. 223
- ^ History of Sveriges Riksbank Riksbank.com Archived 2008-05-04 at the Wayback Machine
- ^ Committee of Finance and Industry 1931 (Macmillan Report) description of the founding of Bank of England. Arno Press. 1979. ISBN 9780405112126. Archived from the original on 1 July 2023. Retrieved 10 May 2010.
Its foundation in 1694 arose out the difficulties of the Government of the day in securing subscriptions to State loans. Its primary purpose was to raise and lend money to the State and in consideration of this service it received under its Charter and various Act of Parliament, certain privileges of issuing bank notes. The corporation commenced, with an assured life of twelve years after which the Government had the right to annul its Charter on giving one year's notice. Subsequent extensions of this period coincided generally with the grant of additional loans to the State.
- ^ H. Roseveare, The Financial Revolution 1660–1760 (1991, Longman), p. 34
- ^ Bagehot, Walter (5 November 2010). Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market (1873). London: Henry S. King and Co. (etext by Project Gutenberg). Archived from the original on 9 May 2012. Retrieved 24 January 2013.
- ^ Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. "A History of Central Banking in the United States" online Archived 29 September 2018 at the Wayback Machine
- ^ Clifford Gomez (2011). Banking and Finance: Theory, Law and Practice. PHI. p. 100. ISBN 9788120342378. Archived from the original on 1 July 2023. Retrieved 29 September 2018.
- ^ Michael D. Bordo; Marc Flandreau; Jan F. Qvigstad (2016). Central Banks at a Crossroads: What Can We Learn from History?. Cambridge UP. pp. 1–17. ISBN 9781107149663. Archived from the original on 1 July 2023. Retrieved 29 September 2018.
- ^ Michael Stephen Smith (2006). The Emergence of Modern Business Enterprise in France, 1800–1930. Harvard UP. p. 59. ISBN 9780674019393. Archived from the original on 1 July 2023. Retrieved 29 September 2018.
- ^ "History". Bank of Finland. Archived from the original on 28 October 2014. Retrieved 28 October 2014.
- ^ Niall Ferguson, The House of Rothschild: Volume 1: Money's Prophets: 1798–1848 (1999).
- ^ Gabriele Teichmann, "Sal. Oppenheim jr. & Cie., Cologne." Financial History Review 1.1 (1994): 69–78, online in English Archived 29 September 2018 at the Wayback Machine.
- ^ Bray Hammond, "Jackson's Fight with the 'Money Power'". American Heritage (June 1956) 7#4: 9–11, 100–103.
- ^ Miklos Sebok, "President Wilson and the International Origins of the Federal Reserve System—A Reappraisal." White House Studies 10.4 (2011): 424–447.
- ^ Marcello De Cecco (1994), Central Banking in Central and Eastern Europe: Lessons From the Interwar Years' Experience, Washington DC: International Monetary Fund
- ^ "Rothschild: history of a London banking dynasty". The Daily Telegraph. Archived from the original on 4 June 2023.
- ^ "10 of the Wealthiest Families in the World".
- ^ Gray, Victor; Aspey, Melanie (May 2006) [2004]. "Rothschild, Nathan Mayer (1777–1836)". Oxford Dictionary of National Biography. Oxford Dictionary of National Biography (Online ed.). Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/ref:odnb/24162. Retrieved 21 May 2007. (Subscription or UK public library membership required.)
- ^ Niall Ferguson, The House of Rothschild: Volume 2: The World's Banker: 1849–1999 (2000)
- ^ Richard Smethurst,"Takahasi Korekiyo, the Rothschilds and the Russo-Japanese War, 1904–1907" Archived 16 February 2007 at the Wayback Machine. Retrieved 4 September 2007.
- ^ Youssef Cassis and Éric Bussière, eds., London and Paris as International Financial Centres in the Twentieth Century (2005) ch 3
- ^ Alain Plessis, "The history of banks in France." in Pohl, Manfred, and Sabine Freitag, eds. Handbook on the history of European banks (Edward Elgar Publishing, 1994) pp: 185–296. online Archived 3 October 2018 at the Wayback Machine
- ^ Joan Comay, Who's who in Jewish History (2001) pp 305–14, 455
- ^ Niall Ferguson, The House of Rothschild: Volume 2: The World's Banker: 1849-1999 (1998) pp 82–84, 206–14, 297–300,
- ^ Ashworth, Herbert (1980). The Building Society Story. London: Franey & Co. p. 4. ISBN 0-900382-38-4.; Berg, Maxine (1991). "Commerce and Creativity in Eighteenth-Century Birmingham". In Berg, Maxine (ed.). Markets and Manufacture in Early Industrial Europe. London: Routledge. p. 194. ISBN 0-415-03720-4. Retrieved 7 September 2010.
- ^ Jones, Peter M. (2009). Industrial Enlightenment: Science, technology and culture in Birmingham and the West Midlands, 1760–1820. Manchester: Manchester University Press. p. 65. ISBN 978-0-7190-7770-8.; Chinn, Carl (15 November 2008). "Brum's building society origins". Birmingham Mail. Birmingham Post and Mail Ltd. Retrieved 6 September 2010.
- ^ Rex, Simon (20 April 2010). "The History of Building Societies". Building Societies Association. Archived from the original on 23 August 2013. Retrieved 6 September 2010.; Ashworth, Herbert (1980). The Building Society Story. London: Franey & Co. p. 2. ISBN 0-900382-38-4.
- ^ Peterson, Christopher L. (July 2003). "Truth, Understanding, and High-Cost Consumer Credit: The Historical Context of the Truth in Lending Act". Florida Law Review (55): 839–840.
- ^ Clark, Peter (2002), British Clubs and Societies 1580–1800: The Origins of an Associational World, Oxford: Oxford University Press, p. 129, ISBN 0-19-924843-5, retrieved 20 November 2010
- ^ Cleary, E. J. (1965). The Building Society Movement. London: Elek Books. pp. 11–12. ISBN 9780236311446. OCLC 11817434. Retrieved 7 September 2010.
- ^ Fortune, Peter (September–October 2000). "Margin Requirements, Margin Loans, and Margin Rates: Practice and Principles – analysis of history of margin credit regulations – Statistical Data Included". New England Economic Review.
- ^ a b "Bank Failures". Living History Farm. Archived from the original on 19 February 2009. Retrieved 22 May 2008.
- ^ "Friedman and Schwartz, Monetary History of the United States", 352
- ^ "Raymond F. Mikesell, The Bretton Woods Debates: A Memoir, Essays in International Finance 192 (Princeton: International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University, 1994)" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 18 June 2017. Retrieved 22 October 2014.
- ^ "How the ATM Revolutionized the Banking Business". Bloomberg.com. Bloomberg News. 27 March 2013.
- ^ "SWIFT History". SWIFT. Archived from the original on 26 December 2012. Retrieved 22 October 2014.
- ^ "In Depth – Big Bang". Financial Times. 29 October 2006. Archived from the original on 15 November 2006. Retrieved 29 October 2006.
- ^ Chairman Cox (26 September 2008). "Chairman Cox Announces End of Consolidated Supervised Entities Program". press release 2008-230. SEC. Retrieved 14 March 2014.
- ^ Investment banking – Is there a future?, 18 September 2008, The Economist
- ^ Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (22 July 2020). "Re: Authority of a National Bank to Provide Cryptocurrency Custody Services for Customers" (PDF). OCC.gov.
- ^ Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (4 January 2021). "OCC Chief Counsel's Interpretation on National Bank and Federal Savings Association Authority to Use Independent Node Verification Networks and Stablecoins for Payment Activities" (PDF). OCC.gov.
- ^ Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (13 January 2021). "OCC Conditionally Approves Conversion of Anchorage Digital Bank". OCC.gov.
- ^ "Bank Guarantee Scheme & Recapitalisation". National Treasury Management Agency. 22 October 2008. Archived from the original on 2 March 2009.
- ^ Journal of the Royal Statistical Society Royal Statistical Society (Great Britain) Statistical Society of London 1874 . Retrieved 15 May 2012
- ^ Josephus Nelson Larned, Donald Eugene Smith, Charles Seymour The new Larned History for ready reference, reading and research: the actual words of the world's best historians, biographers and specialists; a complete system of history for all uses, extending to all countries and subjects and representing the better and newer literature of history, Volume 7 C.A. Nichols Publishing Company, 1923 Retrieved 15 May 2012
- ^ oxforddictionaries
- ^ a b "Walter B. Wriston Archives". Tufts University. Archived from the original on 19 May 2012. Retrieved 14 May 2012.
- ^ Banque de France. "history". Retrieved 18 May 2012.
- ^ a b Kindleberger – p. 12 (see : Sources)
- ^ Hawkins, William, "Panic Control", The Washington Times, 12 May 2008
Further reading
[edit]- Andreades, Andreas Michael. History of the Bank of England (Routledge, 2013)
- Cameron, Rondo. Banking in the Early Stages of Industrialization: A Study in Comparative Economic History (1967)
- Cameron, Rondo et al. International Banking 1870–1914 (1992)
- Cassis, Youssef; Grossman, Richard S.; Schenk, Catherine R., eds. (2016). The Oxford Handbook of Banking and Financial History. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-965862-6.
- Feis, Herbert. Europe the World's Banker, 1870–1914 (1930) online
- Ferguson, Niall. The Ascent of Money: A Financial History of the World (2008).
- Ferguson, Niall. The House of Rothschild: Volume 2: The World's Banker: 1849-1999 (2000)
- Grossman, Richard S. Unsettled Account: The Evolution of Banking in the Industrialized World Since 1800 (Princeton University Press; 2010) 384 pages. Considers how crises, bailouts, mergers, and regulations have shaped the history of banking in Western Europe, the United States, Canada, Japan, and Australia.
- Hammond, Bray, Banks and Politics in America, from the Revolution to the Civil War (Princeton University Press, 1957)
- Hudson, Peter James. "On the History and Historiography of Banking in the Caribbean." Small Axe 18.1 43 (2014): 22–37.
- Jaffe, Steven H., and Jessica Lautin. Capital of Capital: Money, Banking, and Power in New York City (Columbia University Press, 2014)
- Kindleberger, Charles P. – A Financial History of Western Europe ISBN 0415378672
- Klebaner, Benjamin J. American commercial banking: A history (Twayne, 1990). online
- Kobrak, Christopher, and Wilkins, Mira, eds. History and Financial Crisis: Lessons from the 20th Century (Routledge, 2014)
- Komai, Alejandro, and Gary Richardson. "A history of financial regulation in the USA from the beginning until today: 1789 to 2011." in Handbook of Financial Data and Risk Information I (2014): 385+.
- Lane, Nicholas. "The Fathers of English Banking." History Today (Mar 1953) 3#3 pp 190–199
- Meltzer, Allan H. A History of the Federal Reserve (2 vol. U of Chicago Press, 2010) on U.S.
- Michie, Ranald C. British Banking: Continuity and Change from 1694 to the Present (Oxford UP, 2016) 334 pp. online review
- Murphy, Sharon Ann. Other People's Money: How Banking Worked in the Early American Republic (2017) online review
- Neal, Larry. "How it all began: the monetary and financial architecture of Europe during the first global capital markets, 1648–1815." Financial History Review (2000) 7#2 pp: 117–140.
- Rothbard, Murray N., History of Money and Banking in the United States. Full text (510 pages) in pdf format
- Soyeda, Juichi. A history of banking in Japan
External links
[edit]- eabh (The European Association for Banking and Financial History)
- Banking and Bankers at Encyclopedia.com