Overhang seat

Overhang seats are constituency seats won in an election under the traditional mixed-member proportional (MMP) system (as it originated in Germany), when a party's share of the nationwide votes would entitle it to fewer seats than the number of individual constituencies won.

How overhang seats arise

[edit]

Under MMP, a party is entitled to a number of seats based on its share of the total vote. If a party's share entitles it to ten seats and its candidates win seven constituencies, it will be awarded three list seats, bringing it up to its required number. This only works, however, if the party's seat entitlement is not less than the number of constituencies it has won. If, for example, a party is entitled to five seats, but wins six constituencies, the sixth constituency seat is referred to as an overhang seat. Overhang typically results from the winner-take-all tendency of single-member districts, or if the geographic distribution of parties allows one to win many seats with few votes.[1]

Earning overhang seats

[edit]

The two mechanisms that together increase the number of overhang seats are:[2]

  1. winning many constituencies;
  2. decreasing the number of party votes and therefore the number of seats to which the party is proportionally entitled.

In many countries, overhang seats are rare – a party that is able to win constituency seats is generally able to win a significant portion of the party vote as well. There are, however, some circumstances in which overhang seats may arise relatively easily:

  • Few major parties, large number of minor parties – When there are only one or two major parties, but a relatively large number of minor parties that, combined, achieve a significant share of the total proportional vote, but fail to elect any constituency seats, the large parties often end up with overhang seats.
  • Similar lead across constituencies – If one party wins all or most constituencies of a relevant area with a rather low margin, it would be more prone to overhang mandates than if different parties lead in different constituencies, with the same overall share of each of the parties. As such, if there is less difference between constituencies, overhang seats are more probable.
  • A large number of constituencies compared with the total number of seats – If too many seats are used for constituencies, the remainder are less likely to ensure strict proportionality.
  • Unevenly sized constituencies – Candidates that win small constituencies by a narrow margin do not generate enough votes to justify their full seats under a proportional system.
  • Low turnout in some constituencies – This has the same effect as small constituencies. Furthermore, turnout and party preferences may be highly correlated, e.g. rural vs. urban areas.
  • Small number of seats to be allocated – The higher the absolute number of constituencies, the more likely it is that different reasons for overhang seats will balance out between parties. E.g., after the German federal Bundestag election in 2013, the main reason for overhang seats was that some compensation happens for party's state lists instead of at the federal level only.
  • Individual candidates with strong local followings – Sometimes, a particular politician will have strong support in their own constituency, but will belong to a party with very low support, even in their own area. The candidate will be elected based on their own qualities, but the party they belong to will not receive enough votes to justify the candidate's seat. In the case of independent candidates, this is usually guaranteed – they have no party at all, and so obviously cannot win votes under MMP's party-list proportional representation. However, some countries, such as New Zealand, have special rules dealing with independents – seats won by these candidates are exempted from the proportional system altogether.
  • Regional parties – Parties based in a particular region may win a substantial number of constituency seats in that region without necessarily gaining a large share of the national vote. Parties focused on particular ethnic or religious minorities may also come under this category, particularly if seats are reserved for these groups.
  • Tactical voting – Voters in countries that can cast a vote in the list vote and cast a local vote (such as Germany) may decide not to vote for a local candidate that has little chance of winning but still support that party on the list vote. Parties that win many local seats but attract a reduced list vote may receive an overhang as a result.
  • Decoy parties – Party labels in the constituencies can be deliberately mismatched with those in the proportional vote in an attempt to induce tactical voting. In Italy in 2001, two lists won a significant majority of the total number of first-past-the post seats, despite winning almost none of the proportional vote. The system, nicknamed scorporo, was not a type of additional member system in which overhangs could occur, it resulted in a significant distortion to the desired compensatory nature.

Dealing with overhang seats

[edit]

Overhang seats are dealt with in different ways by different systems.

Take the number of additional list seats off from the other parties' proportional entitlement

[edit]

A party is allowed to keep any overhang seats it wins, and the corresponding number of list seats allocated to other parties is eliminated to maintain the number of assembly seats. This means that a party with overhang seats has more seats than its entitlement, and other parties have fewer. This approach is used in the Chamber of Deputies of Bolivia and the National Assembly of Lesotho. It was unsuccessfully recommended by the 2006 Ontario Citizens' Assembly on Electoral Reform for adoption by the Legislative Assembly of Ontario, and the proposed Dual-member proportional representation system uses this approach as well. While for the first additional list seats are simply denied to parties, in the latter three cases[specify], a fairer procedure was proposed of subtracting the constituency seats won by parties with overhang seats from the total number of seats and recalculating the quota (the largest remainder method was also recommended) to proportionally redistribute the list seats to the other parties.

In the Scottish Parliament, Welsh Senedd and London Assembly, the effect is similar, but the mechanism different. In the allocation of second vote list seats using a highest averages method, the first vote constituency seats already won are taken into account when calculating party averages, with the aim of making the overall result proportional. If a party wins more seats in the first vote than its proportion of second votes would suggest it should win overall, or if an independent candidate wins a constituency seat, then the automatic effect is to reduce the overall number of seats won by other parties below what they might expect proportionally.

Allow the overhang

[edit]

A party is allowed to keep any overhang seats it wins, but other parties are still awarded the same number of seats that they are entitled to. This means that a party with overhang seats has more seats than its entitlement. The New Zealand Parliament uses this system;[3] one extra seat was added in the 2005 election and 2011 election, and two extra seats in the 2008 election. This system was also used in the German Bundestag until 2013.

Compensating the overhang

[edit]

Other parties may be given additional list seats (sometimes called "balance seats" or leveling seats) lest they be disadvantaged. This preserves the same ratio between parties as was established in the election. It also increases the size of the legislature, as overhang seats are added, and there may also be extra list seats added to counteract them. This system results is less proportional than full compensation, as the party with the overhang is still receiving a "bonus" above its proportional entitlement. After the Federal Constitutional Court of Germany ruled in 2008 that allowing uncompensated overhang seats unconstitutional (because in rare instances, it allowed votes to negatively affect the number of seats for a given party, contradicting the voter's will), leveling seats were introduced for the 2013 election and also used in those of 2017 and 2021.

Non-awarding of overhang seats

[edit]

A party is not allowed to keep any overhang seats it wins, with its number of seats actually being reduced until it fits the party's entitlement. This method raises the question of which constituency seats the party is not allowed to keep. After that is determined, it would then have to be decided who, if any, will represent these constituencies. This was used in the Landtag of Bavaria until 1966, with the candidates with the lowest number of votes not keeping the constituency seat.

This system is now in place at the federal level in Germany, starting with the forthcoming 2025 election. As with the previous system in Bavaria, overhanging constituency winners are excluded in order of lowest vote share.[4]

Constitutionality

[edit]

Prior to German reunification overhang mandates - particularly at the federal level - were relatively rare and never amounted to more than five (out of over 400 total seats) in any given Bundestag and several federal elections resulted in no overhang at all.[5] This was in part due to the relative strength of the two major parties, CDU/CSU and SPD; with both parties winning large shares of the vote in the pre-reunification three-party system, it was rare for either to win more than a handful of overhanging constituencies.[6][7]

However, this began to change as East Germany started participating in German federal elections starting with the 1990 German federal election, with the PDS posting particularly strong results in those states. This along with the rise of Alliance '90/The Greens served to depress the party-list vote shares, creating more overhang seats than in prior elections.

In the 1994 German federal election, the re-elected Kohl government supported by a "black-yellow" coalition (CDU/CSU and FDP) achieved a relatively slim majority of 341 out of 672 seats to the opposition's (SPD, Alliance 90/The Greens, PDS) 331 seats at the opening session. This majority would have been even narrower if not for twelve overhang seats the CDU/CSU had achieved, which were however partially mitigated by the four overhang seats for the SPD.[8] This led to much more public debate on the existence of overhang seats and what to do about them.[9][10][11][12] There was even a challenge of the validity of the election result based on the overhang seat issue raised by a private citizen after the 1994 election, which was however dismissed as "obviously without merit".[13]

The problem thus turning from a theoretical consideration to a real issue, the German Constitutional Court as early as 1997 ruled that a "substantial number" of overhang mandates which weren't equalized through leveling seats were unconstitutional.[14] The issue became more pressing after a particularly notorious case of negative vote weight at the 2005 election. The election in the constituency Dresden I was held two weeks later than the other 298 constituencies after the death of a candidate. Der Spiegel published an article in the intervening time outlining how more votes for the CDU could lead to them losing an overhang seat, and thus narrowing their plurality in the close election.[15] The anticipated tactical voting in Dresden I did occur as Andreas Lämmel (CDU) won the constituency with roughly 37% of the constituency vote while his party won only 24.4% of the party-list vote, with the FDP receiving 16.6% - more than one and a half times their federal vote share of 9.8%.[16]

This led to another ruling by the German Constitutional Court in 2008 which ruled that the existing federal electoral law was unconstitutional in part as it violated the principle of one person one vote and produced an overly opaque relationship between the numbers of votes cast and seats in parliament.[17][18][19][20] However, the Court also allowed for a three year deadline to change the electoral law, allowing for the 2009 German federal election to be held under the previous set of rules.

The electoral reform passed with the votes of the governing "black-yellow" coalition in late 2011 (a few weeks after the deadline set in 2008) - and without consulting the opposition parties - was again ruled unconstitutional by the Constitutional Court.[21][18] Furthermore, the Court clarified that the federal electoral system was supposed to be primarily one of proportional representation and a number of non-compensated overhang seats above 15 would "dilute" this proportional character.[22][23]

As the Bundestag thus lacked a constitutional electoral mechanism[24] and the 2013 German federal election was coming up, the government agreed to negotiations with the opposition parties, leading to a new electoral law being passed in early 2013 with broad support from all parties in the Bundestag except Die Linke.[25] This added leveling seats and was used in the 2013, 2017 and 2021 elections.

On the state level, an unclear wording in the state electoral law of Schleswig-Holstein led to different possible assignments of leveling seats to equalize the overhang seats ultimately resulting in the 2009 Schleswig-Holstein state election giving a majority of seats to the Peter Harry Carstensen led "black-yellow" coalition, despite them having won a lower share of the vote than the SPD, Greens, Left, SSW opposition. Following a suit before the State Constitutional Court brought by opposition parties,[26] it was ruled that the electoral law in its then current interpretation did indeed violate the state constitution but that the Landtag was to keep its composition until a new electoral law could be passed (which happened in 2011) after which new elections would be scheduled with enough time for campaigns setting the next election for 2012, two years earlier than if the Landtag had served its full five year term.[27]

The 2023 reform which eliminated the awarding of all overhang and leveling seats was also subject to a constitutional challenge. The Federal Constitutional Court upheld this part of the law.[28]

Examples

[edit]

Germany

[edit]

In the system used in Germany through the forthcoming 2025 election, every constituency seat won by any party or an independent is granted, while the electoral system requires that a party needs 5% of the party-list vote to win list seats. If a party wins at least three constituency seats, it is granted full proportional representation as if it passed the 5% electoral threshold, even if it did not. The awarding of overhang seats and the leveling seats required to compensate for this led to a drastic increase in the size of the Bundestag beyond its normal size of 598 members.

In the 2021 federal election, The Left fell just short of the election threshold with 4.9% of the national vote but won three single-member constituency seats.[29] This entitled them to proportional representation in the Bundestag according to their second votes.[30] The extra compensation seats for other parties meant that the Bundestag would be the largest in German history, and in fact the largest freely elected parliament in the world, with 736 MPs.[31]

In 2023, in response to the increasing size of the Bundestag, the Scholz cabinet passed a reform law to fix the size of future Bundestags at 630 members beginning with the 2025 election. This is achieved by eliminating all overhang and leveling seats. A party's total number of seats will be determined solely by its share of party-list votes (Zweitstimmendeckung, "second vote coverage"). If a party wins overhanging constituency seats in a state, its constituency winners in excess of its share of seats would be excluded from the Bundestag in order of those that received the smallest vote shares. The rule allowing any party winning three constituency seats to receive full proportional representation was originally also abolished. The Federal Constitutional Court, however, decided that a 5% electoral threshold with no exceptions was unconstitutional and the rule was restored on an interim basis for the 2025 election.[28]

New Zealand

[edit]

In New Zealand, Te Pāti Māori (the Māori Party) usually gets less than 5% of the party votes, the threshold required to enter parliament – unless the party wins an electorate seat. Te Pāti Māori won one overhang seat in 2005 and 2011, and two overhang seats in 2008.[32] In 2005 their share of the party vote was under 2% on the initial election night count, but was 2.12% in the final count which included special votes cast outside the electorate. On election night it appeared that the party, whose candidates had won four electorate seats, would get two overhang seats in Parliament. However, with their party vote above 2% the party got an extra seat and hence needed only one overhang seat. National got one less list seat in the final count, so then conceded defeat (the result was close between the two largest parties, National and Labour). Te Pāti Māori won six electorate seats in 2023, two more than its 3.08% share of the party vote entitled it to; and shortly after the general election, the Port Waikato by-election resulted in a further overhang seat for National.[33]

See also

[edit]

Notes

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ "Reasons for overhang seats". www.wahlrecht.de. Retrieved 14 June 2021.
  2. ^ "Handling Overhang Seats". www.wahlrecht.de. Retrieved 14 June 2021.
  3. ^ New Zealand Government. "Electoral Act 1993, Section 192(5)". Retrieved 7 October 2023.
  4. ^ Germany passes law to shrink its XXL parliament
  5. ^ Der Bundeswahlleiter (20 September 2021). "Überhangmandate - Der Bundeswahlleiter". Bundeswahlleiter.de. Retrieved 25 November 2021.
  6. ^ Karl-Rudolf Korte (7 January 2021). "Bundestagswahlrecht im Meinungsstreit: Überhangmandate und Grundmandatsklausel | bpb" (in German). M.bpb.de. Retrieved 25 November 2021.
  7. ^ Ein Gastbeitrag von KR-Mitglied Frank Heber (3 September 2020). "Die Reform des Wahlrechts, verständlich erklärt". Krautreporter.de. Retrieved 25 November 2021.
  8. ^ http://www.bpb.de/politik/wahlen/bundestagswahlen/62538/wahlrecht-im-meinungsstreit?p=all [dead link]
  9. ^ Matthias Wies (Autor:in) (15 December 2006). Überhangmandate - Ein umstrittenes Element im Bundeswahlgesetz. GRIN. Retrieved 25 November 2021.
  10. ^ "Irrtum 8: Überhangmandate sind weniger wichtig".
  11. ^ Sturm, Daniel Friedrich (17 February 2009). "Bundestagswahl: Warum Überhangmandate ein Machtfaktor sind". Die Welt.
  12. ^ "Geschichte der Überhangmandate im Deutschen Bundestag".
  13. ^ "Bundestag – Wahleinspruch – Überhangmandate (30.11.1995) – Bundestagswahl 1994".
  14. ^ "BVerfG: Ausgleichslose Überhangmandate sind verfassungsgemäß".
  15. ^ Wittrock, Philipp; Todt, Jens (19 September 2005). "Nachwahl: Warum die Union in Dresden nicht gewinnen darf". Der Spiegel.
  16. ^ "Microsoft PowerPoint - Deckblatt_Bundestagswahl_2005_gesamt" (PDF). Retrieved 25 November 2021.
  17. ^ "Bundesverfassungsgericht - Entscheidungen - Verfassungswidrigkeit des Effekts des negativen Stimmgewichts im Zusammenhang mit Überhangmandaten und der Möglichkeit von Listenverbindungen durch Regelungen des Bundeswahlgesetzes: Verletzung der Grundsätze der Gleichheit und Unmittelbarkeit der Wahl - Wahlfehler führt aber nicht zur Auflösung des 16. Deutschen Bundestages". 3 July 2008.
  18. ^ a b "Wahlrechtsreform". 31 May 2012.
  19. ^ "BVerfG – BVerfGE 121, 266 – 2 BVC 1/07, 2 BVC 7/07 – Wahlprüfungsbeschwerden – Negatives Stimmgewicht (03.07.2008)".
  20. ^ "Urteil über Überhangmandate Wahlrechtsgerechtigkeit". 3 July 2008.
  21. ^ "Bundesverfassungsgericht - Entscheidungen - Neuregelung des Sitzzuteilungsverfahrens für die Wahlen zum Deutschen Bundestag verfassungswidrig". 25 July 2012.
  22. ^ "Wahlrecht – News – zum Urteil des Bundesverfassungsgerichts vom 25. Juli 2012".
  23. ^ "Wahlrecht verfassungswidrig | DW | 25.07.2012". Deutsche Welle.
  24. ^ "Der Bund steht ohne Wahlrecht da". 25 July 2012.
  25. ^ "Das neue Wahlrecht und die Krux mit den Überhangmandaten | BPB".
  26. ^ "Koalition steht – Wahlergebnis wackelt". Der Tagesspiegel Online.
  27. ^ Rath, Chr (30 August 2010). "Urteil in Schleswig-Holstein: Neuwahl - aber erst in zwei Jahren". Die Tageszeitung: Taz.
  28. ^ a b Frank Bräutigam; Kolja Schwartz. "Bundesverfassungsgericht kippt das neue Wahlrecht in Teilen". tagesschau.de (in German). Archived from the original on 30 July 2024. Retrieved 30 July 2024.
  29. ^ "Factbox: German 'traffic light' coalition seen as most likely". Reuters. 27 September 2021. Retrieved 27 September 2021.
  30. ^ "Germany votes: Big gains for center-left parties, heavy losses for conservatives — as it happened". Deutsche Welle. 27 September 2021. Archived from the original on 26 September 2021. Retrieved 27 September 2021.
  31. ^ "Germany begins new parliamentary era". Deutsche Welle (DW). 26 October 2021. Retrieved 5 November 2021.
  32. ^ Green, Antony (22 September 2017). "New Zealand election guide". ABC News. Retrieved 14 June 2021.
  33. ^ "The $5m cost of Parliament's 3 overhang MPs - and how only 29% is salary". The New Zealand Herald. 12 December 2023. Retrieved 12 December 2023.