Sequential proportional approval voting

Flow chart of SPAV calculation

Sequential proportional approval voting (SPAV) or reweighted approval voting (RAV)[1] is an electoral system that extends the concept of approval voting to a multiple winner election. It is a simplified version of proportional approval voting. It is a special case of Thiele's voting rules, proposed by Danish statistician Thorvald N. Thiele in the early 1900s.[2] It was used (with adaptations for party lists) in Sweden from 1909 to 1921, when it was replaced by a cruder "party-list" style system as it was easier to calculate,[3][4] and is still used for some local elections.

Description

[edit]

Sequential Proportional Approval Voting (SPAV) uses Approval Voting ballots to elect multiple winners equitably by selecting a candidate in each round and then reweighing the approvals for the subsequent rounds.[5]

Each ballot is assigned a value equal to the reciprocal of one more than the number of candidates approved on that ballot who have been designated as elected. Each ballot is counted at its current value as a vote for all continuing candidates approved on that ballot. The candidate with the most votes in the round is elected. The process continues until the number of elected candidates is equal to the number of seats to be filled.[6]

At each stage, the unelected candidate with the highest approval score is elected. Then the value of each voter’s ballot is set at where s is the number of candidates approved on that ballot who were already elected, until the required number of candidates is elected. This reweighting is based on the D'Hondt method (Jefferson method). Other weighting formulas such as Sainte-Lague method may be used while still being referred to as SPAV.

There is an incentive towards tactical voting where a voter may withhold approval from candidates who are likely to be elected in any case, as with cumulative voting and the single non-transferable vote.

It is a much computationally simpler algorithm than harmonic proportional approval voting, permitting votes to be counted either by hand or by computer, rather than requiring a computer to determine the outcome of all but the simplest elections.[7]

When comparing Sequential Proportional Approval Voting to Single Transferable Vote, SPAV is better at selecting more central candidates, that represent all the voters, where STV is better at mimicking the distribution of the voters.[8]

Example

[edit]
Illustration of the example election. Candidates with the most votes wins for each round. When a candidate is elected they are removed for the next round.

For this example, there is an election for a committee with 3 winners. There are six candidates from two main parties: A, B, and C from one party, and X, Y, and Z from another party. About 2/3 of the voters support the first party, and the other roughly 1/3 of the voters support the second party. Each voter casts their vote by selecting the candidates they support. The following table shows the results of the votes. Each row starts by saying how many voters voted in that way and marks each candidate that group of voters supported. The bottom row shows the number of votes each candidate received.

Votes from 200 voters
# of votes Candidate A Candidate B Candidate C Candidate X Candidate Y Candidate Z
112
6
4
73
4
1
Total Votes 116 122 126 82 78 77

Because Candidate C has the most support, they are the first winner, w1, and their vote is not counted in later rounds. For the second round, anyone who voted for Candidate C has their vote counted as only 1/2. Below is the chart for round 2. A second column on the left has been added to indicate the weight of each ballot.

Second Round Results
# of votes Weight of Vote Candidate A Candidate B Candidate C Candidate X Candidate Y Candidate Z
112 1/2
6 1/2
4 1/2
73 1
4 1/2
1 1
Weighted Votes 58 61 78 76 75

Despite Candidates A and B having so many votes in the first round, Candidate X is the second winner, w2, because not as many of the votes for Candidate X were halved. In round 3, anyone who voted for either Candidates C or X has their vote count 1/2, and anyone who voted for both has their vote count 1/3. If anyone had voted for neither, their vote would remain at 1. Below is that table.

Third Round Results
# of votes Weight of Vote Candidate A Candidate B Candidate C Candidate X Candidate Y Candidate Z
112 1/2
6 1/2
4 1/3
73 1/2
4 1/3
1 1/2
Weighted Votes 57 1/3 60 1/3 38 1/3 37 5/6

Candidate B is the third and final winner, w3. The final result has 2/3 winners from the party that had about 2/3 of the votes, and 1/3 winner from the party that had about 1/3 of the votes. If approval voting had been used instead, the final committee would be all three candidates from the first party, as they had the highest three vote totals without scaling.

Properties

[edit]

Sequential-PAV satisfies the fairness property called justified representation whenever the committee size is at most 5, but might violate it when the committee size is at least 6.[9][10]


Pareto efficiency Committee monotonicity Support monotonicity with additional voters Support monotonicity without additional voters Consistency inclusion- strategyproofness Computational complexity
Approval voting strong P
Proportional approval voting strong × cand × NP-hard
Sequential Proportional Approval Voting × cand cand × × P

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ Brams, Steven; Brill, Markus (2018). "The Excess Method: A Multiwinner Approval Voting Procedure to Allocate Wasted Votes". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.3274796. ISSN 1556-5068. S2CID 53600917.
  2. ^ E. Phragmén (1899): "Till frågan om en proportionell valmetod." Statsvetenskaplig tidskrifts Vol. 2, No. 2: pp 87-95 [1] Archived 2015-06-18 at the Wayback Machine
  3. ^ Lewis, Edward G. (1950). "Review of Modern Foreign Governments". The American Political Science Review. 44 (1): 209–211. doi:10.2307/1950372. ISSN 0003-0554. JSTOR 1950372. S2CID 152254976.
  4. ^ Humphreys, John H. (2006-01-01). Proportional Representation: A Study in Methods of Election. Archived from the original on 2022-05-11. Retrieved 2022-05-11.
  5. ^ Kilgour, D. Marc (2010). "Approval Balloting for Multi-winner Elections". In Jean-François Laslier; M. Remzi Sanver (eds.). Handbook on Approval Voting. Springer. pp. 105–124. ISBN 978-3-642-02839-7.
  6. ^ Steven J. Brams, D. Marc Kilgour (2009): "Satisfaction Approval Voting": p4 [2] Archived 2012-06-28 at the Wayback Machine
  7. ^ Aziz, Haris; Serge Gaspers, Joachim Gudmundsson, Simon Mackenzie, Nicholas Mattei, Toby Walsh (2014). "Computational Aspects of Multi-Winner Approval Voting". Proceedings of the 2015 International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems. pp. 107–115. arXiv:1407.3247v1. ISBN 978-1-4503-3413-6.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  8. ^ Faliszewski, Piotr; Skowron, Piotr; Szufa, Stanisław; Talmon, Nimrod (2019-05-08). "Proportional Representation in Elections: STV vs PAV". Proceedings of the 18th International Conference on Autonomous Agents and MultiAgent Systems. AAMAS '19. Richland, SC: International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems: 1946–1948. ISBN 978-1-4503-6309-9. Archived from the original on 2022-05-11. Retrieved 2022-05-11.
  9. ^ Sánchez-Fernández, Luis; Elkind, Edith; Lackner, Martin; Fernández, Norberto; Fisteus, Jesús; Val, Pablo Basanta; Skowron, Piotr (2017-02-10). "Proportional Justified Representation". Proceedings of the AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence. 31 (1). arXiv:1611.09928. doi:10.1609/aaai.v31i1.10611. ISSN 2374-3468. S2CID 17538641. Archived from the original on 2021-06-24. Retrieved 2021-06-24.
  10. ^ Aziz, H., Brill, M., Conitzer, V., et al. (2014): "Justified Representation in Approval-Based Committee Voting", arXiv:1407.8269 p5 [3] Archived 2017-04-13 at the Wayback Machine